BP-275E
ECONOMIC UNION:
A COMPARISON OF
CANADIAN GOVERNMENT PROPOSALS AND
THE PLANS OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY
Prepared by:
Anthony Chapman
Economics Division
October 1991
TABLE
OF CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION
THE
EUROPEAN COMMUNITY: BACKGROUND AND INSTITUTIONS
A. Background
B.
The Main Decision-Making Institutions of the European Community
1.
The European Commission
2.
The Council of Ministers
3.
The European Parliament
4.
The European Council
ECONOMIC
INTEGRATION IN THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY
A. The Single European
Act
B. Europe 1992:
The Single Market Plan
1. Removal of Physical
Barriers
2. Removal of Technical
Barriers
a. Standards
b.
Public Procurement
c. Free
Movement of Labour and Professionals
d.
Common Market for Services
3.
Removal of Fiscal Barriers
C. Economic and Monetary
Union
COMPARISON
OF EEC TREATY WITH PROPOSED SECTION 121
OF
THE CONSTITUTION
A. Prohibition
on Internal Barriers
1. The Canadian
Government Proposals
2. The European
Economic Community Rules
3. Analysis
B.
Exceptions to the Prohibition on Internal Barriers
1. The Canadian
Government Proposals
2. The European
Economic Community Rules
a. Exceptions
to the Free Movement of Goods
b. Exceptions
to the Free Movement of Persons
c.
Exceptions to the Free Movement of Services
d. Exceptions
to the Free Movement of Capital
e.
Other Exceptions
3. Analysis
COMPARISON
OF EEC INTEGRATION PROCESS WITH PROPOSED
NEW
CONSTITUTIONAL POWER
A.
The Canadian Government Proposals
B.
Economic Integration in the European Community
C. Analysis
IMPROVING FINANCIAL
SECTOR REGULATION
A. Canadian
Government Proposals
B.
The European Economic Community Rules
C. Analysis
CO-ORDINATION
AND HARMONIZATION OF MACROECONOMIC POLICIES
A. Canadian
Government Proposals
B.
The European Community Proposals
C. Analysis
CONCLUSION
REFERENCES
ECONOMIC UNION:
A COMPARISON OF
CANADIAN GOVERNMENT PROPOSALS AND
THE PLANS OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY
INTRODUCTION
On 24 September 1991, the
Canadian government released a 59-page document, "Shaping Canadas
Future Together: Proposals," designed to serve as the basis for discussion
on the shape of Canadas political and economic future. Among the
controversial proposals were those intended to remove internal economic
barriers and restrictions and to strengthen the coordination and harmonization
of macroeconomic policies. These ideas to promote Canadian economic integration
were further elaborated upon in the document "Canadian Federalism
and Economic Union: Partnership for Prosperity," released on 26 September.
While Canada has recently
been facing a real possibility of political, and perhaps economic, fragmentation,
on the other side of the Atlantic Ocean the European Community is implementing
an ambitious program to integrate 12 national markets into a single internal
market that would lead eventually to economic and political union. What
Canada can learn from European integration was illustrated in "The
European Community a Political Model for Canada," one of the
background papers accompanying the release of the governments proposals.
Although clearly there are political differences between the EC confederal
model and the Canadian federation, the EC may offer some lessons for Canada
on economic integration. Indeed, the similarities between the EC integration
plans and the Canadian economic union proposals suggest that these lessons
were studied carefully by the federal government.
The first section of this
paper provides some background information on the EC, including its origins
and main decision-making institutions. The second part summarizes "Europe
1992" and "Economic and Monetary Union" (EMU) plans to
integrate the EC economically. The third section compares the Canadian
governments proposals for economic union with the process of European
integration.
THE
EUROPEAN COMMUNITY: BACKGROUND AND INSTITUTIONS
A. Background
The European Community is
composed of three Communities; first, the European Coal and Steel Community
(ECSC) was formed by the Treaty of Paris (1951) in order to integrate
the coal and steel markets of Belgium, France, Italy, Luxembourg, the
Netherlands and West Germany; second, the European Atomic Energy Community
(Euratom), formed by the same six countries in the Treaty of Rome
(1957), was aimed at co-ordinating and encouraging the development of
nuclear power for peaceful purposes; third, the European Economic Community
(EEC) originated with another Treaty of Rome (1957) establishing
a common market that would lay the foundations for political and economic
union. While legally there are three Communities, they now share the same
institutions and budget and from a political standpoint they are viewed
as a single "European Community."
In order to understand the
process of European integration it is useful to have some knowledge of
the European Communitys institutions and decision-making procedure.
The next section identifies the primary EC institutions and outlines their
respective roles in the Communitys decision-making process. It is
important to recognize that the EC is an association of countries which
have chosen to be constrained by supranational institutions. The EC institutions
cannot act independently of a majority of the member states. There is
a vast difference between the EC government, which has no power to raise
revenues directly through taxation but must rely on contributions from
member states, and the Canadian federation, where the central government
has its own wide-ranging taxation powers and can act independently of
the constituent governments.
B.
The Main Decision-Making Institutions of the European Community
1.
The European Commission
The European Commission,
consisting of 17 members appointed by agreement of the member states and
assisted by over 15,000 employees, "is the engine of Community policy,
the guardian of the treaties, and the advocate of the Community interest."
The Commission is charged with initiating proposals, which are examined
and voted upon by other decision-making bodies. For instance, the Commission
proposed the "White Paper on Completing the Internal Market"
(Europe 1992) and is responsible for drafting the legal instruments to
implement the program. The Commission is also responsible for administering
and supervising the treaties, including applying treaty rules to governments
and firms. (For competition reasons, the Commission recently blocked the
purchase by a European consortium of Canadian aircraft manufacturer de Havilland.)
2.
The Council of Ministers
It has been said that the
Commission proposes and the Council disposes. After a Commission initiative
is considered by the European Parliament, it is voted upon by the Council
of Ministers, which directly represents the member states governments.
Membership of the Council is nominally composed of the foreign ministers
of member governments but in practice membership changes with the topic
under discussion. For instance, when agriculture is being discussed each
country sends the Minister of Agriculture or the Ministers deputy
to the meeting. The position of President of the Council is held for six
months by each member state in rotation.
Although the EEC Treaty
established the principle of majority voting by the Council of Ministers
on most issues, under the so-called "Luxembourg compromise"
any member state had the right to block a decision that went against its
vital national interest. This effectively gave member states the right
to veto proposals to which they objected. The amendments to the EEC Treaty
by the Single European Act considerably expanded the use of majority
voting by the Council. A "qualified majority" in the Council
of Ministers is defined as 54 votes out of a total of 76 votes. The distribution
of voting rights in the Council is as follows: U.K., Germany, France and
Italy have 10 votes each; Spain has 8 votes; Belgium, Greece, the Netherlands
and Portugal have 5 votes each; Denmark and Ireland have 3 votes each;
Luxembourg has 2 votes.
3.
The European Parliament
Although the 518-member
European Parliament is now directly elected by voters in the member states,
it does not have the power to propose legislation or even to defeat or
amend proposals initiated by the Commission if the Council of Ministers
chooses to override this. The European Parliaments role is mainly
that of a consultative body which considers and provides its opinion on
Commission proposals. However, the Parliament does have the power to reject
proposed budgets and, by a two-thirds majority, force the resignation
of the whole body of commissioners.
4.
The European Council
The European Council, which
includes the heads of member states governments, should not be confused
with the Council of Ministers. The European Council was not provided for
in the original EEC Treaty but was institutionalized at the Paris summit
of 1974, where it was agreed that the leaders and their foreign ministers,
along with the President of the Commission and one of the Vice-Presidents
of the Commission, would meet regularly. Subsequently enshrined in the
Single European Act, the European Council provides the necessary
political impetus to initiate Intergovernmental Conferences on significant
reforms such as the single market program, economic and monetary union
and political union.
ECONOMIC
INTEGRATION IN THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY
A.
The Single European Act
Although the 1957 Treaty
of Rome establishing the European Economic Community (EEC) envisaged the
elimination of internal barriers to the free movement of goods, persons,
services and capital (the "four freedoms"), the progress towards
this goal was slow after tariffs and internal quotas were removed by 1968.
In fact, during the late 1970s and early 1980s rising domestic unemployment
combined with competition from Far Eastern countries increased protectionism
among member states.
In 1985 the Commission of
the European Community presented to the European Council a White Paper,
"Completing the Internal Market," proposing more than 300 directives
(later reduced to 279) intended to break down internal market impediments
to the full realization of the four freedoms. These internal barriers
were categorized as physical, technical or fiscal in nature. The proposed
remedy came to be known as "Europe 1992" because of the 31 December
1992 deadline for full implementation of the plan.
The Single European Act
(SEA), the first major revision of the EEC Treaty, set the goal of establishing
the internal market and made the necessary changes to the Treaty to enable
the introduction and passage of the Europe 1992 program. The SEA facilitated
the decision-making procedure by stipulating that qualified majority voting
be used for measures which have as their object the establishment and
functioning of the internal market. Exceptions were made for fiscal provisions
and those relating to the free movement of people and to the rights and
interests of employed persons.
Another important feature
of the SEA was the incorporation in the EEC Treaty of the principle of
"mutual recognition." Article 100B of the Treaty requires the
Commission during 1992 to draw up an inventory of laws, regulations and
administrative provisions which have not been harmonized. The Council
may decide, on the basis of a qualified majority, to declare the provisions
in force in a member state to be equivalent to those applied by another
member state. Finally, the SEA laid the groundwork for proposals for economic
and monetary union and for political union, which were subsequently put
forward.
B. Europe 1992:
The Single Market Plan
1. Removal of Physical
Barriers
-
Abolition
of border checks of goods and persons by removing the underlying reason
for them through:
-
Standardization
of customs forms; elimination of bilateral permits rationing truck
transportation between countries; adoption of EC-wide quotas against
restricted outside country goods; removal of the need for adjustment
of agricultural prices at internal borders; harmonization of VAT and
excise taxes (fiscal measures); harmonization of product health standards
(technical standards); approximation of drug and arms legislation.
2. Removal of Technical
Barriers
a. Standards
b.
Public Procurement
-
Opening
national public procurement to foreign suppliers by: closing loopholes
in existing EC rules governing national procurement; providing firms
with the right to take legal action with respect to how government
contracts are awarded; enhancing supervision of member state procurement
practices; and opening up to outside bidding the previously excluded
sectors of energy, transport, telecommunications and water.
c. Free Movement
of Labour and Professionals
d. Common Market for Services
-
Integration
of the European financial services market by: harmonization of capital
adequacy standards and accounting requirements for financial institutions;
mutual recognition of other member states application of essential
standards; home country control whereby supervision of the sale of
financial products will primarily be the responsibility of authorities
in a financial institutions home country;
-
Removal
of bilateral road transportation quotas and opening up rail, inland
waterways, maritime transport, and air to more competition;
-
Opening
up to competition certain "value-added" communication services,
such as fax, vision and data transmission;
-
Removal
of internal restrictions on the free flow of capital (although there
is provision for derogation by member states for reasons of domestic
monetary regulation, to control exceptional exchange rate movements
or to prevent infringement of national laws.) Delayed implementation
of the capital movement directive until the end of 1992 for Spain,
Ireland, Portugal and Greece;
-
Laws to
encourage cross-border industrial cooperation, worker participation
in management of companies, mergers across borders and protection
of intellectual property.
3.
Removal of Fiscal Barriers
-
Approximation
of VAT rates within bands in each country to remove the need for border
controls on cross-border shoppers;
-
Establishment
of minimum excise tax rates for tobacco and alcohol and a range of
rates for mineral oils.
C. Economic and Monetary
Union
A three-stage plan has been
established for the monetary and economic union of the EC. In stage one,
monetary and economic policies would be more tightly coordinated and the
currencies of Britain, Portugal and Greece would join the European Monetary
System (EMS).
In stage two, currency fluctuations
would be more tightly controlled, a European System of Central Banks (ESCB)
would be established and macroeconomic policies would be coordinated by
the European Council compromising the heads of member states and governments.
In the third stage, exchange
rates would be fixed permanently and national monetary units would be
replaced by a common currency. Monetary policy would be determined by
the European Central Bank (ECB) operating through the ESCB. The EC would
establish binding guidelines for the budgetary policies of member states.
COMPARISON
OF EEC TREATY WITH PROPOSED SECTION 121
OF THE
CONSTITUTION
A. Prohibition on Internal
Barriers
1. The Canadian
Government Proposals
The Canadian government
proposes to amend section 121 of the Constitution to prohibit federal
or provincial laws, programs or practices that create barriers or restrictions
to the free movement of persons, goods, services and capital. The first
two parts of the proposed section 121 would read as follows:
(1) Canada is an economic
union within which persons, goods, services and capital may move freely
without barriers or restrictions based on provincial or territorial
boundaries.
(2) Neither the Parliament
or Government of Canada nor the legislatures or governments of the provinces
shall by law or practice contravene the principle expressed in subsection
(1).
2. The European
Economic Community Rules
Article 3 of
the Treaty establishing the European Economic Community states that the
activities of the Community shall include:
(a) the elimination,
as between Member States, of customs duties and of quantitative restrictions
on the import and export of goods, and of all other measures having
equivalent effect;
(c) the abolition,
as between Member States, of obstacles to freedom of movement for persons,
services and capital.
The Single European Act,
which provides for the integration of the internal market (Europe 1992),
amended Article 8A to the EEC Treaty. This states: "The internal
market shall comprise an area without internal frontiers in which the
free movement of goods, persons, services and capital is ensured in accordance
with the provisions of this Treaty."
Article 5 requires member
states to carry out their obligations under the Treaty and to "abstain
from any measure that could jeopardize the attainment of the objectives
of this Treaty."
Member states obligations
with respect to the four freedoms (goods, persons, services and capital)
are expanded upon in the Treaty: free movement of goods (Articles 9-37);
free movement of persons (Articles 48-58); free movement of services (Articles
59-66); free movement of capital (Articles 67-73).
Article 95 of the Treaty
prohibits the imposition of higher taxes on products of other member states
than on similar domestic products. Internal taxation measures must not
provide indirect protection to other products.
Article 2 of the Draft Treaty
on Economic and Monetary Union would amend the objectives of the EEC Treaty
to state that the task of the Community is to achieve economic and monetary
union.
3. Analysis
Among sovereign states,
a treaty is the main legal instrument for restraining the behaviour of
national governments. By the Treaty of Rome, the signatories have agreed
to permit the free flow between EC member states of good, persons, services
and capital. In a federation such as Canada, the Constitution provides
the primary legal instrument for binding constituent governments. The
existing protection for the Canadian common market derives mainly from
two sections of the Constitution. The first, section 121, provides that:
"All Articles of the Growth, Produce, or Manufacture of any one of
the Provinces shall, from and after the Union, be admitted free into each
of the other Provinces."
As it stands, section 121
of the Canadian Constitution provides for unimpeded interprovincial trade
in goods only; interprovincial trade in services, labour and capital is
not included. Second, it is unclear whether existing section 121 applies
to foreign-made goods in addition to those produced within the provinces.
Third, the section seems to apply to duties but not to non-tariff barriers.
Fourth, the section appears to constrain the provincial governments but
not the federal government.
The second protection for
the Canadian common market derives from section 91 of the Constitution,
which gives the federal government exclusive legislative authority over
"the Regulation of Trade and Commerce." Although Canadian courts
have interpreted this section as granting the federal government exclusive
jurisdiction over international and interprovincial trade, this has been
circumscribed by the exclusive constitutional powers granted the provinces
over "Property and Civil Rights in the Province" and "Generally
all Matters of a merely local or private nature in the Provinces."
These provisions have permitted the provinces to erect an array of interprovincial
non-tariff trade barriers.
The government proposal
to strengthen the Constitutions common market clause and expressly
to prohibit federal or provincial measures limiting the four freedoms
would likely provide the Canadian courts with a more active role in striking
down internal economic barriers. Courts in the United States and the European
Community have been significant forces for market integration.
In the European Community,
member states obligations set out in the Treaty of Rome are enforceable
under EC law and the European Court of Justice has proved to be one of
the most powerful forces for integration of the EC internal market. One
noteworthy example is the Cassis de Dijon case. The European Court
of Justice ruled in this case that West Germany could not block the importation
of the French liqueur, Cassis de Dijon, simply because it did not
contain the required minimum 32% level of alcohol necessary to qualify
as a liqueur under West German standards. This ruling has been instrumental
in striking down other disguised trade barriers in the EC such as the
German beer purity law and Italian regulations requiring pasta to be made
exclusively from durum wheat. There are numerous other cases where the
European Court has ruled against market impediments.
Unlike the proposed Canadian
constitutional amendment, the existing EEC Treaty does not call the EEC
an "economic union." However, the draft amendments to the EEC
Treaty proposed by the Commission state that "the Community
shall have as its task progressively to achieve economic and monetary
union."
B.
Exceptions to the Prohibition on Internal Barriers
1. The Canadian
Government Proposals
The Government has proposed
that the prohibition on trade barriers would make exceptions for regional
development policies or laws declared by Parliament to be in the national
interest. Proposed subsection 121(3) in the Constitution states:
(3) Subsection (2) does
not render invalid:
(a) a law of the Parliament
of Canada enacted to further the principles of equalization or regional
development
(b) a law of a provincial
legislature enacted in relation to the reduction of economic disparities
between regions wholly within a province that does not create barriers
or restrictions that are more onerous in relation to persons, goods,
services or capital from outside the province than it does in relation
to persons, goods, services or capital from a region within the provinces;
or
(c) a law of the Parliament
of Canada or of the legislature of a province that has been declared
by Parliament to be in the national interest.
(4) A declaration referred
to in paragraph (3)(c) shall have no effect unless it is approved by
the governments of at least two-thirds of the provinces that have in
aggregate, according to the then latest general census, at least 50%
of the population of all the provinces.
2. The European
Economic Community Rules
a. Exceptions
to the Free Movement of Goods
Article 36 of the EEC Treaty
permits prohibitions or restrictions on trade in goods where this is "justified
on the basis of public morality, public policy or public security; the
protection of health and life of humans, animals or plants; the protection
of national treasures possessing artistic, historic or archaeological
value; or the protection of industrial property and commercial property."
These prohibitions or restrictions must not constitute a means of arbitrary
discrimination or a disguised restriction on trade between member states.
b. Exceptions
to the Free Movement of Persons
Article 48(3) of the EEC
Treaty permits member states to exclude persons from its territory "on
grounds of public policy, public security or public health." Member
states discretion in applying the public policy proviso is circumscribed
by EC law. An individuals conduct must constitute a genuine and
serious threat to public policy and affect one of the fundamental interests
of society. For instance, diseases such as tuberculosis or syphilis, drug
addiction, and profound mental disturbance might be construed as threatening
public health. An individuals conduct might also constitute a reason
for exclusion from the territory of a member state if it posed a genuine
and serious threat to public security and affected one of the fundamental
interests of society. Article 48(4) states that the freedom of movement
for workers established in Article 48 does not apply to employment in
the public service.
c. Exceptions
to the Free Movement of Services
Services are considered
"services" within the meaning of the Treaty insofar as they
are not governed by the provisions relating to freedom of movement for
goods, capital and persons. This implies that member states may impose
restrictions on foreign persons selling services within their borders.
Thus, restrictions on grounds of public policy, public health or public
security could apply, as in the case of freedom of movement for persons.
Restrictions might also apply where the provider of services performs
activities that are connected, even occasionally, to the exercise of official
authority. (Article 55)
d. Exceptions
to the Free Movement of Capital
The existing EEC Treaty
permits a member state to take protective measures to prevent disturbances
in its capital market (Article 73) or to overcome balance of payments
difficulties (Articles 108 and 109). However, the draft amendments to
the Treaty for economic and monetary union would prohibit restrictions
on the movement of capital. (The repeal of Articles 68 to 73 has still
to be considered.)
e.
Other Exceptions
Article 100A, which was
amended to the Treaty by the Single European Act, provides in paragraph
4 a derogation from the harmonization of laws and regulations where a
"Member State deems it necessary to apply national provisions on
grounds of major needs referred to in Article 36, or relating to the protection
of the environment or the working environment
" (Note the earlier
reference to Article 36 relating to exceptions to the free movement for
goods.) The member state must notify the European Commission of national
provisions which derogate from the harmonization of laws provided for
in Article 100A. The Commission must confirm the national provisions after
determining that they are not a means of arbitrary discrimination or a
disguised restriction on trade.
Article 8C of the EEC Treaty
directs the Commission when drawing up its single market proposals to
"take into account the extent of the effort that certain economies
showing differences in development will have to sustain during the period
of the establishment of the internal market." Any derogations must
be temporary and impose the least possible disturbance to the functioning
of the internal market.
3. Analysis
Although they appear numerous,
the derogations in the EEC Treaty from the common market principle tend
to be for specific reasons (i.e., health and safety, the environment,
etc.) The European Court of Justice, the final arbiter of what constitutes
acceptable derogations, has interpreted these exceptions strictly. In
a number of cases where a member state has used, for instance, health
and safety as grounds for restricting imports, the Court has found these
derogations to be unjustified.
By contrast, the exceptions
in the Canadian government proposal are fewer in number but more general
in nature. The exceptions for regional development and laws declared in
the national interest provide ample room for deviation from the economic
union principle. The requirement that exceptions for laws declared in
the national interest be ratified by the provinces using the 7/50 formula
does provide a brake on the use of this derogation.
Although the existing EEC
Treaty does not allow for opting out upon agreement, a proposed amendment
to the EEC Treaty dealing with economic and monetary union would introduce
an innovation in Community law. Upon a qualified majority vote by the
Council of Ministers (with at least eight member states in favour), member
states in economic difficulty would be permitted to derogate temporarily
from full participation in the final stage of economic and monetary union.
COMPARISON
OF EEC INTEGRATION PROCESS WITH PROPOSED
NEW
CONSTITUTIONAL POWER
A. The Canadian Government
Proposals
The Government is proposing
the creation of a new constitutional power for the Parliament of Canada
that would allow it exclusively to pass legislation for the efficient
functioning of the economic union. However, these laws would have no effect
unless approved by the governments of at least two thirds of the provinces
that have, in the aggregate, at least 50% of the population of all the
provinces. Furthermore, the legislative assembly of any province could
declare by a resolution supported by 60% of its members that these laws
did not apply in the province, although such a declaration would expire
after three years unless an earlier expiry date was specified in the declaration.
The Government is also proposing
the formation of a "Council of the Federation," which would
ratify the legislation enacted under this new constitutional power. Although
the Governments proposals do not state this explicitly, they imply
that the Council would consist of representatives from each province and
that the required provincial approval (by at least two-thirds of the provinces)
would take place in the Council.
Pending the coming into
force of new section 121 of the Constitution on 1 July 1995, the Government
proposes that the Council of the Federation be used by governments to
address the problem of internal barriers.
B. Economic
Integration in the European Community
As outlined earlier, the
European Commission is responsible for initiating EC legislation while
the European Parliament reviews the legislation and votes on it. It is
the member states themselves, however, represented on the Council of Ministers,
which finally have the power to adopt or defeat proposed legislation.
Although this legislative
process applies to laws that fall within the ambit of the EC treaties,
initiatives requiring revisions to the treaties, such as the Single
European Act, Economic and Monetary Union, and European Political
Union, have first been placed before the heads of governments at meetings
of the European Council. This body has then authorized intergovernmental
conferences to hammer out agreed amendments to the treaties. The revised
treaties enter into force after ratification by the national legislatures
of the member states. The specific EC laws to implement the proposals
are introduced by the Commission and pass through the EC legislative process.
As an example, take the
Europe 1992 program. This plan began with the "White Paper on Completing
the Internal Market" published by the European Commission and presented
to the European Council in 1985. Over the objections of Britain, Denmark
and Greece, the European Council voted to hold an intergovernmental conference
to draft the necessary enabling amendments to the EEC Treaty. The result
of that conference, the Single European Act, was signed and ratified
by all 12 member states and came into force in 1987.
With the parameters of the
EEC Treaty sufficiently broadened, the European Commission has been putting
the 279 separate measures of the White Paper into EC law. At this point,
over two-thirds of the proposals have passed through the required legislative
process and have been adopted by the Council of Ministers. About two-thirds
of the measures to implement the single market require a qualified majority
vote by the Council (54 votes out of 76). Measures concerned with harmonization
of taxes, free movement of persons and the rights and interests of employed
persons can still be blocked in the Council of Ministers by a single country.
Much of the single market
program is being implemented by EC Directives, legal instruments that
do not enter into force in a member state until transposed into national
law. At May 1991, about three-quarters of the directives adopted by the
Council of Ministers had been transposed into national law. The single
market proposals are also being implemented through EC regulations, which
are directly binding on member states without the introduction of domestic
legislation. Decisions, also legal instruments, are EC Commission instructions;
these are binding in their entirety on the governments, companies or individuals
to whom they are addressed.
C. Analysis
The creation of a new constitutional
power to make laws for the efficient functioning of the Canadian economic
union would permit the federal government to introduce a single market
plan for Canada along the lines of "Europe 1992." The ratification
of such measures by the provincial governments in a new Council of the
Federation according to the 7/50 rule can be compared with the EC legislative
requirement for a qualified majority vote by the Council of Ministers.
It is worth noting, however, that EC member states have reserved the right
to veto certain measures to implement the single market. This would not
be possible under the Canadian proposal.
It would be possible under
the Canadian proposal for a province to derogate from laws made under
the economic union power for a period of up to three years. The EEC Treaty,
by contrast, does not provide member states with the option of temporary
derogation simply by a vote of the national legislature. However, with
the agreement of the Council of Ministers, member states in economic difficulty
would be permitted to derogate temporarily from participation in the final
stage of economic and monetary union. As noted earlier, the EC Single
European Act did direct the Commission, when drawing up the plan to
complete the internal market, to take into account the need for temporary
derogations by less developed member states. The implication is, however,
that such a derogation would have to be justified on specific grounds
and be approved by the Commission.
IMPROVING FINANCIAL
SECTOR REGULATION
A. Canadian Government
Proposals
The Governments paper
recognizes the unnecessary costs imposed on Canadian financial institutions
(and ultimately on consumers) by overlapping federal and provincial regulation.
For instance, a federally incorporated or provincially incorporated trust
or loan company operating across the country could potentially face 10
or 11 sets of rules in its Canada-wide operations.
The paper states that:
the Government intends
to address the issue of overlap and duplication in the regulation of
trust companies.
Many have argued that Canada should adopt some
version of Europe 1992, which envisages the creation of a single European
financial market
This would involve each jurisdiction recognizing
and accepting, for regulatory purposes, the prudential regime of the
jurisdiction within which a financial institution is chartered, subject
to acceptable basic standards.
The federal government
is prepared to explore with the provinces the possibility of moving
toward a regulatory regime based on lead jurisdiction or mutual recognition.
For federally incorporated [trust and loan] companies, such arrangement
could be achieved by provinces delegating their administrative and regulatory
power to the federal government.
With respect to securities
regulation, the Government is prepared to explore an approach where all
jurisdictions could delegate all or part of securities regulation to a
jointly operated agency. Other approaches include "more formalized
federal-provincial action to co-ordinate approaches to regulation, international
negotiation and standard-setting for securities."
B. The European
Economic Community Rules
Liberalization of financial
markets under the 1992 program depends upon three principles. The first
principle, harmonization, requires member states to agree upon common
standards of capital adequacy, solvency and accounting requirements for
financial institutions. The second principle, mutual recognition, means
that member states must trust the others application of the common
standards laid out by the Council. The third principle, home country control,
signifies that supervision of the sale of financial products will primarily
be the responsibility of authorities in a financial institutions
home country. (Host country control will continue to apply with respect
to the liquidity of credit institutions and measures affecting monetary
policy and reserve requirements for operations of credit institutions
in securities markets.) Underlying these three principles is the requirement
that capital be permitted to move freely across borders.
The ultimate goal of these
liberalization measures is to enable a financial institution to sell financial
services across borders or to establish branches in other member states
without facing regulatory overlap and duplication. The principles of harmonization,
mutual recognition and home country control would apply to the regulation
of banking services, investment services and, eventually, insurance services.
C.
Analysis
Under the EC plan, banks
and building societies (essentially deposit-taking institutions) complying
with harmonized capital adequacy and solvency standards would be provided
with a "single banking licence" permitting the sale of a defined
menu of banking services anywhere in the Community, providing their home
(chartering) country did not prohibit them from offering these services.
The services authorized by the single banking licence could be offered
in a member state even if the host country did not permit its own firms
to sell these. This could give rise to foreign chartered firms selling
financial services that domestically chartered firms were not authorized
to sell. Obviously, there will be pressure for countries that define banking
services more narrowly to harmonize their services with the menu of services
authorized by the single banking licence. Otherwise, domestically chartered
firms could be placed at a disadvantage.
Because the Canadian proposals
on improving financial sector reform lack specifics, it is difficult to
determine how the government intends the principles of harmonization,
mutual recognition and home country rule to operate in Canada. One possibility
would be to adopt the EC model practically intact and authorize institutions
to sell throughout Canada a specific set of financial services based on
acceptance of certain prudential standards by all provinces. As in the
EC, jurisdictions authorizing the sale of fewer financial services by
an institution would be encouraged by competitive pressures to bring their
services into harmony with those authorized by the single licence. However,
a drawback is the intrusion into provincial jurisdiction that this implies.
An alternative interpretation
of the EC model applied to Canada was offered by the May 1990 Report "Canada
1992: Toward a National Market in Financial Services" issued by the
Standing Senate Committee on Banking, Trade and Commerce. This system
would still require a consensus on key prudential standards (harmonization),
primary regulation by the chartering province (home country control) and
mutual recognition of this regulation by other provinces. The key difference
between this "designated jurisdiction" model and the EC plan
is the requirement for host-province licensing and compliance with the
menu of services authorized by the host province.
An example of the application
of the designated jurisdiction model may help to illustrate. Suppose a
trust company chartered in Quebec, which allows the sale of insurance
on the premises of deposit-taking institutions, also operated in Ontario,
where the sale of insurance on premises is not currently permitted. Under
the designated jurisdiction model, the trust company would not be permitted
to sell insurance on premises in Ontario. It could only do in Ontario
what an Ontario chartered firm was permitted to do.
At the same time, Quebec
would accord to trusts operating in Quebec but chartered outside the province
the same privileges as Quebec chartered firms. The main advantage of the
designated jurisdiction model over the status quo is that regulation
would primarily be the responsibility of the chartering jurisdiction.
In the case of the Quebec trust company operating in Ontario, Quebec would
regulate the firms overall capital and solvency standards and Ontario
would not attempt to duplicate this. And, in contrast to the EC model,
each province could maintain its own conduct of business rules within
its jurisdiction without pressure to harmonize these with a specific menu
of financial services.
CO-ORDINATION
AND HARMONIZATION OF MACROECONOMIC POLICIES
A. Canadian
Government Proposals
The government proposes
to develop a more open and visible federal and provincial budget-making
process that would include:
-
a relatively
fixed budget cycle;
-
a fixed
annual schedule of Finance Ministers meetings;
-
the publication
by the 11 governments of pre-budget economic/fiscal outlooks;
-
common accounting
conventions.
The government proposes
to develop, with the provinces, guidelines to improve the coordination
of fiscal policies and the harmonization of fiscal policies with Canadas
monetary policy. For example, budgets might have to be balanced over the
full course of the business cycle. (A balanced budget could be defined
to exclude expenditures on capital formation.) These guidelines would
be set in legislation under the proposed new economic power. Accordingly,
this would require agreement of at least seven of the ten provinces with
at least 50% of the population.
The government proposes
the establishment of an independent agency to monitor and evaluate the
macroeconomic policies of the federal and provincial governments.
The Bank of Canada Act
would be amended to make it clear that the Banks mandate is to achieve
and preserve price stability. Canadas regions would be represented
on the Board of Directors of the Bank of Canada by individuals nominated
by the federal government after consultation with provincial governments.
Regional consultative panels would be created to advise the Directors
of the Bank on regional economic conditions. The appointment of the governor
of the Bank of Canada would be subject to Senate ratification. To increase
the transparency of monetary policy, the Governor of the Bank of Canada
would be required to testify regularly before Parliament. The Governor
would also be required to meet with the federal and provincial Ministers
of Finance to present views on the state of the economy and the interaction
of monetary policy and fiscal policy.
B. The European Community
Proposals
The Single European Act
introduced into the EEC Treaty the objective of achieving economic and
monetary union. Article 102A requires member states to cooperate "in
order to ensure the convergence of economic and monetary policies which
is necessary for the further development of the Community."
The Report of the Delors
Committee, released in April 1989, set out a three-stage plan to achieve
the goal of economic and monetary union. The conclusions of the report
were endorsed by the European Council meeting in Madrid in July 1989.
At the Rome meetings of the European Council in October and December 1990,
11 of the 12 members agreed to follow the concept of EMU put forward by
the Delors plan and to convene an intergovernmental conference. (The United
Kingdom was the sole objector to the EMU plan.)
Stage 1 During the
first stage of EMU, which came into effect on 1 July 1990, member states
monetary and economic policies are to be more tightly coordinated. Monetary
and economic plans are to be submitted to the EC Commission and Ecofin
(Council of Ministers for Economics and Finance). The currencies of Britain,
Portugal and Greece are expected to joint the European Monetary System
(EMS). Currencies are to be allowed to fluctuate within plus or minus
2.25% of the central rate.
Stage 2 The second
stage is set to begin on 1 January 1994. Currency fluctuations would be
more tightly controlled, a European Central Bank (ECB) and a European
System of Central Banks (ESCB) similar to the U.S. Federal Reserve System
would be established and begin determining ED-wide monetary policy. Macroeconomic
policies would be coordinated by the European Council, which would set
guidelines for individual countries and decide on remedies for member
states that ran excessive budget deficits.
Stage 3 A precise
date for commencement of this stage has yet to be established. Exchange
rates would be fixed permanently and national monetary units would be
replaced by a common currency. The ECB/ESCB would determine EC monetary
policy. The European Commission would submit multi-annual guidelines (normally
three to five years) to the European Council on:
- the development of member states budget
balances;
-
the control
of production costs;
-
the level
and promotion of savings and investment;
-
the adaptation
of Community policies for achieving economic and social cohesion;
-
the development
of structural policies.
Where a member state failed
to implement the multi-annual guidelines, the Commission might make recommendations
to the Council regarding the necessary policy adjustments. Financial assistance
could be offered to member states in financial difficulty.
Proposed Article 104A would
prohibit financing budget deficits through direct assistance from the
European System of Central Banks or by privileged access by public authorities
to the Capital market. The community would not be permitted to guarantee
the public debt of a member state. Excessive budget deficits would have
to be avoided by member states.
Monetary policy would be
set by a majority on the Council of the Bank according to the formula
of one person, one vote. The Council of the Bank would include the 12
governors of the national central banks along with the six-member Executive
Board of the ECB including the President. The members of the Executive
Board of the ECB would be appointed for a period of eight years by the
European Council after the Council of the Bank had given its opinion.
In the case of the appointment of the President and Vice-President, the
European Parliament would be consulted also.
In a limited number of clearly
defined cases relating to decisions on capital, transfer of reserve assets
and profits of the ECB, a system of weighted voting is proposed. Members
of the Executive Board would not vote and the votes of the national central
bank governors would be weighted according to the relative size of each
member states economy.
According to the Draft Statute
for the European System of Central Banks (ESCB) and the European Central
Bank (ECB), the primary objective of the System will be to maintain price
stability. However, the second objective states, "without prejudice
to the objective of price stability, the System shall support the general
economic policy of the Community." Although the ECB/ESCB would have
responsibility for conducting foreign exchange operations, decisions regarding
the exchange rate regime would be made in conjunction with the Ecofin
Council.
Implementation of the final
stage of EMU could be delayed for member states in financial difficulty
where the Council of Ministers voted to permit a temporary derogation.
C.
Analysis
The Canadian proposals for
co-ordination and harmonization of economic policies appear to incorporate
the following aspects of the EC plan for economic and monetary union:
-
co-ordination
of fiscal policies and harmonization with monetary policy;
-
binding
multi-annual economic policy guidelines that would be ratified by
a Council;
-
restricting
the use of deficit financing by governments;
-
surveillance
of macroeconomic policies by a monitoring agency (in the EC this would
be the Commission);
-
regional
representation on the Board of the central bank.
The Canadian proposals would
make achieving and preserving price stability the sole mandate of the
Bank of Canada. The European Central Bank (ECB) would be given the specific
goal of maintaining price stability. Nevertheless, the ECBs secondary
objective, to support the economic policy of the Community, raises questions
about the Banks degree of freedom to pursue the goal of price stability.
There would be the possibility of conflicting objectives if the ECB were
expected to support general economic policy, for example by reducing unemployment,
while simultaneously maintaining price stability. Furthermore, exchange
rates would be partially determined in the political arena, according
to guidelines laid down by the Council of Ministers (Ecofin). Again, there
is the possibility of conflicting central bank objectives.
Although the government
intends to increase regional representation on the Board of Directors
of the Bank of Canada, there is no mention of permitting the Board to
participate in the formulation of monetary policy. Currently, monetary
policy is decided by the Governor of the Bank of Canada in consultation
with the senior Deputy Governor and with the advice of the staff of the
Bank; the Board of Directors may be consulted on regional economic conditions
but it has little direct influence on the countrys monetary policy.
By contrast, regional representation
would be much more strongly felt at the European Central Bank (ECB). The
Draft Statute of the ECB indicates that monetary policy in the EC would
be decided by a majority vote of the Council of the Bank, which would
include the 12 national central bank governors and the six-member Executive
Board.
CONCLUSION
Since the 1930s it has been
well established that "beggar-my-neighbour" trade policies are
ultimately self-defeating. While it is theoretically possible for a large
country to make itself better off by erecting trade barriers, these gains
can be erased if other countries follow suit; the result is a decline
in world economic output. Since World War II, Canada and other countries
have used the GATT and separate trade agreements to lower international
trade barriers. Yet, despite progress at the international level, the
Canadian internal market remains fragmented by numerous interprovincial
trade barriers. Aside from the anachronism these present now that the
country is moving toward international free trade with both the U.S. and
Mexico, internal barriers cost Canadian jobs and economic output.
The Canadian government
proposals would enshrine in law the principle of free movement for persons,
goods, services and capital and would prohibit laws that contravene this
principle. Experience in the EC, however, indicates that merely establishing
the principle of the four freedoms in law is not sufficient to clear away
internal barriers; an active approach is also necessary. It was for this
reason that the EC introduced a legislative program (Europe 1992) that
directly addresses the remaining internal market impediments.
The Canadian governments
proposals also admit that a revised common market clause in the Constitution
might not address the full range of trade barriers. Consequently, the
government proposes that Parliament should have the power to make laws
to remove internal impediments. (Perhaps the government intends to introduce
a "Canada 1992" program to completely integrate the Canadian
internal market.) As in the EC, these laws would be subject to ratification
in a "Council" by a specific majority of member states/provinces.
The Canadian proposals also
admit exceptions to the four freedoms principle on the specific grounds
of furthering regional development or equalization. Beyond this, governments
could exclude a law from application of the economic union clause if Parliament
declared the exclusion to be in the national interest and if this was
ratified according to the 7/50 formula. Furthermore, a province that did
not agree with laws made by Parliament under the new economic union power
could unilaterally opt out by declaration with the support of 60% of the
provincial legislature.
By contrast, trade barriers
within the EC must be justified on specific grounds, such as health and
safety; the EEC Treaty does not currently permit a nation to opt out of
objectionable provisions, either with agreement of a majority of member
states, or by a majority vote of its own national legislature. However,
the draft treaty for economic and monetary union would allow member states
in financial difficulty to delay implementing the final stage of EMU if
the Council of Ministers agreed to a temporary derogation.
The Canadian proposals for
improving regulation of financial institutions are borrowed from the "Europe
1992" program, which established the principles of harmonization,
mutual recognition, and home country control. Application of these principles,
which were more fully developed for the Canadian context in the May 1990
report of the Standing Senate Committee on Banking, Trade and Commerce,
would be a significant step towards reducing regulatory overlap and duplication
in this countrys financial sector.
Like the EC, the Canadian
government is proposing to improve co-ordination of fiscal policy and
harmonization of fiscal policy with monetary policy. With the agreement
of provincial governments (7 provinces and 50% of the population),
the Canadian government would be able to establish binding guidelines
restricting the use of deficit financing by governments. As in the EC,
the macroeconomic policies of governments would be monitored and assessed
by an agency.
With respect to monetary
policy, Canada already has a central bank and a single currency, items
that the EC is proposing to introduce. The Canadian government is suggesting
that the Bank of Canada be provided with the single goal of achieving
and preserving price stability. While this would also be the primary objective
of the European Central Bank, subordinate and potentially conflicting
goals are also proposed for that Bank.
It is uncertain how much
power the Canadian government expects Bank of Canada Directors would exercise
under the proposed rules. Providing more effective regional representation
would move the Bank of Canada in the direction of the European Central
Bank, where 12 of the 18 members of the Bank Council would be national
central bank governors appointed directly by the individual member states.
There is no evidence, however, that the Canadian government is suggesting
that the Board of Directors of the Bank of Canada would take an active
role in the formulation of monetary policy along the lines proposed for
members of the Council of the European Central Bank.
In conclusion, while there
are considerable differences between the EC and the Canadian political
systems, it appears that the Canadian government has drawn some lessons
from the economic integration plans of the European Community. Not only
would the government proposals strengthen the Canadian common market by
ensuring the realization of the four freedoms, they would open the door
to full economic union through the co-ordination and harmonization of
fiscal policies. At first glance, some of these proposals may appear dramatic
but when examined alongside the plans of the European Community, which
is, after all, an association of sovereign states, they do not seem extraordinary.
REFERENCES
Belford, J. ed.. Law
and Practice under the GATT and Other Trading Arrangements The
European Community: The Single Market. Oceana Publications, New York,
1989.
Borchardt, Klas-Dieter.
European Unification The Origins and Growth of the European Community.
Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg,
February 1987.
Brealey, Mark and Conor
Quigley. Completing the Internal Market of the European Community
1992 Handbook. Graham & Trotman, London, 1989.
Buhart, Jacques and Dennis
Burton. Legal Aspects of the Single European Market A Working
Guide to 1992. Euromoney Publication PLC, London, 1989.
Bulletin of the European
Communities, Supplement 2/91. Intergovernmental Conferences: Contributions
by the Commission. Office for Official Publications of the European
Communities, Luxembourg, 1991.
Canada. Canadian Federalism
and Economic Union Partnership for Prosperity. Supply and Services
Canada, Ottawa, 1991.
Canada, Department of Justice.
The Constitution Acts 1867 to 1982. Supply and Services Canada,
1989.
Canada, Senate of Canada,
Standing Senate Committee on Banking, Trade and Commerce. Canada 1992
Toward a National Market in Financial Services. Supply and
Services Canada, Ottawa, May 1990.
Canada. Shaping Canadas
Future Together Proposals. Supply and Services Canada, Ottawa,
1991.
Chapman, Anthony. Europe
1992: The External Implications. BP-225E. Parliamentary Research Branch,
Library of Parliament, January 1990.
Commission of the European
Communities. Sixth Report of the Commission to the Council and the European
Parliament concerning the implementation of the White Paper on the Completion
of the Internal Market. COM(91) 237 FINAL, Brussels, 19 June 1991.
Courchene, Thomas J.
In Praise of Renewed Federalism. C.D. Howe Institute, Toronto, 1991.
The Economist Intelligence
Unit. European Trends. London, (various issues).
Europe Documents. Draft
Statute of the European System of Central Banks and of the European Central
Bank. Europe Agence Internationale dInformation Pour la Presse,
Brussels, Belgium, 8 December 1990.
Laidler, David E.W. How
Shall We Govern the Governor? A Critique of the Governance of the
Bank of Canada. C.D. Howe Institute, Toronto, 1991.
Leslie, Peter M. The
European Community A Political Model for Canada? Supply and
Services Canada, Ottawa, 1991.
Lodge, Juliet ed. The
European Community and the Challenge of the Future. St. Martins
Press, New York, 1989.
Lomax, David F. "A
European Central Bank and Economic and Monetary Union," National
Westminster Bank Quarterly Review, May 1991.
Noel, Émile. Working
Together The Institutions of the European Community. Office
for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg, 1988.
Schmitz, Gerald. The
Pathbreaking Politics of European Integration. BP-240E, Parliamentary
Research Branch, Library of Parliament, November 1990.
|