88-13E
REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN CANADA
Prepared by:
Guy Beaumier
Economics Division
Revised 27 October 1998
TABLE OF CONTENTS
ISSUE
DEFINITION
BACKGROUND
AND ANALYSIS
A.
An Emerging Issue
B.
Early Policy -- 1958-1968
C.
The Creation of DREE
D.
The Creation of DRIE
E.
The 1987 Restructuring
F.
Summary
CHRONOLOGY
SELECTED
REFERENCES
REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT
IN CANADA*
ISSUE
DEFINITION
Almost from the
beginning of Confederation, the federal government has implemented programs
that affected some regions more profoundly than others. Such programs
were never part of a federal regional development policy, however, until
the 1960s, when federal politicians became aware of differences in the
levels of regional prosperity and accepted the responsibility for eliminating
them.
The Rowell-Sirois
and Gordon Royal Commissions and the advent of a serious recession in
the late 1950s focused attention on the persistent regional disparities.
Until that time, authorities had believed that government policies aimed
at stimulating national economic growth would ensure that all regions
benefited. While this was true during periods of growth, the disparities
did not disappear and improvements were achieved only at the cost of severe
social dislocations.
Federal efforts
to formulate development policies and to implement programs aimed at reducing
regional disparities led to the creation of the Department of Regional
Economic Expansion (DREE) in 1969. Later, this department would be amalgamated
with the Department of Industry, Trade and Commerce to become the Department
of Regional Industrial Expansion (DRIE), which assumed responsibility
for both regional and industrial development in Canada. In 1987 DRIE was
disbanded and federal regional development efforts were entrusted to regionally
based development agencies.
This paper reviews
federal regional development policy since World War II, a period in which
both the federal and provincial governments have expended considerable
resources in trying to narrow regional disparities in Canada.
BACKGROUND
AND ANALYSIS
A.
An Emerging Issue
Though regional
disparities have existed in Canada since Confederation, this was not at
first perceived as a problem separate from that of achieving steady national
economic growth. During the Great Depression, however, the differences
in the unemployment rates between the provinces became too pronounced
to ignore. The subsequent deterioration of provincial fiscal capacities
led to the establishment of the Rowell-Sirois Commission, which examined
the devastating impact of the depression on the finances of the provinces
and in its 1940 report recommended a massive restructuring of federal-provincial
fiscal arrangements. The Commission found that, as the provinces had different
capacities for providing services, Canadians could not expect the same
levels of service from each province at uniform national tax rates. It
was suggested that the fiscal capacity of Canadian provinces be equalized
through the transfer of funds from the richer regions to the poorer regions.
Implementation of the Commission's recommendations had to be delayed until
after the end of the war, when the federal and provincial governments
met in a series of conferences which addressed the problems of sharing
the fiscal base in Canada. The result was the now familiar system of equalization
payments which are made to the disadvantaged provinces.
The Royal Commission
on Canada's Economic Prospects (the Gordon Commission) of 1957 explicitly
recognized the existence of regional disparity in Canada. It gradually
became evident that differences existed not only in fiscal capacities
but also in opportunities for growth. The Gordon Commission defined the
regional problem as a difference or gap between a province's level of
income, or unemployment, or other such key variable, and that of another
province or that of the national average. These economic differences between
provinces became known as disparity gaps. It also became evident at this
time that, regardless of the national level of prosperity, the gaps did
not disappear. They might narrow or widen in line with changes in the
national rate of economic growth but the relative differences between
the rich and poorer provinces seemed to persist over time. If regional
disparities were to be eliminated, it could no longer be considered sufficient
for less developed areas to grow at the same rate as the more prosperous
regions of the country; they would have to grow at much faster rates.
This view of the problem was to have a profound effect on subsequent thinking
about regional policies.
Three specific
problems are associated with these definitions of the regional development
issue. First, to designate provinces as the areas of discussion is generally
believed to have been inappropriate because economic regions do not necessarily
conform to political boundaries. Over the years, federal regional development
policies have attempted to define the optimum areas in Canada in which
to implement policy. No universally acceptable definition has yet been
accepted, however, though some sub-regions (such as Cape Breton Island)
have readily been identified. For the most part, provinces remain the
basic geographic unit because most data are available at that level of
aggregation and because of the importance of the provincial governments
in the overall process of economic development.
The second major
problem with this early work was the notion of a disparity gap. The disparity
gap, an easily identifiable phenomenon, has on many occasions been mistaken
for the regional development problem itself. Defining the problem in terms
of a disparity gap in provincial employment levels for instance, has led
to a formulation of policies that concentrate on employment; that is,
policies that mask the symptoms but do not eliminate the problem. In fact,
the existence of a gap in unemployment rates, or in productivity, or in
income levels, may be explained by a host of factors acting alone or together
on the local economy. Each factor responsible for a disparity gap will
often require a different policy solution.
It is important
to understand the causes of regional disparities in order to prescribe
the correct policy approach. While these causes are numerous, they may
be classified in five broad categories. First, there are illusory differences,
for example those in such variables as per capita income, which do not
reflect actual differences between regions. In such instances, policy
actions are not required at all. Second, there are differences in the
natural endowments of local economies, such as the existence of a desirable
geographical feature. Again, this may not require any specific policy
response. A third cause of regional inequality may be certain federal
or provincial actions, which, once identified, can simply be eliminated.
Regional disparity may also "market imperfections," such as
monopolies or unionization. Depending on policy objectives and the precise
nature of the imperfection a number of policy options could be considered.
A final cause could be structural differences such as "factor endowments"
and consumer preferences. Such differences are usually best overcome by
allowing market forces to work; this implies labour mobility. Alternatively,
political considerations may suggest a policy that involves the subsidization
of production. Of course, the regional disparities in Canada may be caused
by a mixture of these factors and this will make it more difficult to
identify the correct policy response. More importantly, it is highly likely
that the source of regional inequality will differ from one part of the
country to the next and that this will reduce the effectiveness of any
policy that seeks a universal solution through one national program.
A third problem
with the Gordon Commission's study of regional disparity was its view
of resource development and industrial development. Since Canada's central
provinces had a highly developed manufacturing sector, it became conventional
practice until very recently to associate development with increased manufacturing
employment. This ignored the fact that the best opportunities for developing
a region may well be in the resource sector.
In spite of these
flaws, the apparent successes of stabilization policies in the post-war
period led to a widely accepted notion that it was no longer sufficient
for governments to compensate the victims of economic circumstances; rather,
governments could and should eliminate the causes of these hardships.
Therefore, when the problem of regional disparity was identified, it seemed
natural to suggest, as the Gordon Commission did, that the federal government
ought to solve it.
However, the prosperity
of the Canadian economy during the first decade after World War II did
not foster any sense of urgency in government to deal with the problem.
In fact, because economic growth was rapid, and since all regions shared
in this prosperity, the regional problem did not surface as a priority
item on the government agenda until much later. Though a province might
have accepted a slower growth rate during periods of prosperity, it was
seldom prepared to accept differences in unemployment rates during a recession.
B.
Early Policy -- 1958-1968
The recession of
the late 1950s forced the federal government to take action to alleviate
regional disparities. One initiative was the Winter Works Programs of
1958-59 and 1959-60. Designed as a short-term expedient, they represented
an innovative approach to solving local unemployment problems through
shared cost programs and they demonstrated that locally targeted programs
were feasible.
Though faced with
short-term cyclical problems, however, most initiatives of this period
tended to focus on correcting long-term structural aspects of regional
economies. There was, for instance, an attempt to upgrade human capital
with the introduction of the Technical and Vocational Training Assistance
Program, which provided funds on a cost-shared basis to the province for
the training of the provincial labour force. This was followed later by
the Occupational Training Act, which included both manpower and
mobility measures designed to deal with structural unemployment.
Other major initiatives
of this period were: the Agricultural Rehabilitation and Development Program
(ARDA), whose purpose was to improve the standard of living of farmers
on marginal land; the Fund for Rural Economic Development (FRED), which
was designed to provide federal-provincial rural development programs
in designated areas; the Atlantic Development Board, which administered
the Atlantic Development Fund for financing development projects in Atlantic
Canada; and the Area Development Agency (ADA), which promoted economic
development in high unemployment areas through financial incentives for
manufacturing enterprises.
The federal government
programs of the 1960s were designed and implemented to deal with specific
problems. These early attempts at correcting regional disparities enjoyed
only moderate success because of the absence of an overall strategy for
development and of coordination among the various federal government departments
responsible for their administration. Each program addressed specific
problems of economic development and each was planned and administered
by a separate government department. Furthermore, line departments made
their own arrangements with their provincial counterparts so that the
federal government might have several unrelated development plans in a
single province. Under such conditions, the federal and provincial governments
might not pursue common goals and could not work out strategies for economic
development. By the end of the 1960s, there was a clear need for a centralized
federal agency that could coordinate the federal regional development
effort and enter into cooperative agreements with the provinces.
C.
The Creation of DREE
In order to provide
greater cohesion to its regional development efforts, the federal government
created the Department of Regional Economic Expansion (DREE) in 1969,
with the aim of promoting economic expansion and social adjustment in
the disadvantaged regions of Canada. Former federal programs were either
replaced by new DREE programs or incorporated directly into the new department.
DREE was to focus its efforts on 23 areas of the country (growth poles)
from which further development would spin off into the regions. At these
growth poles, DREE offered assistance for improving infrastructure, for
implementing social adjustment measures, and for helping private investment
in a designated area. The efforts of the new department would be focused
on eastern Canada, with as much as 80% of DREE's expenditure to be spent
east of Trois-Rivières. Even these expenditures were to be concentrated
into the selected growth poles in the belief that this would create new
opportunities for economic growth in Eastern Canada's urban centres.
Growth pole theory
assumes that economic development tends to occur around certain focal
points or poles and that growth does not proceed equally in all places
at the same intensity because different areas offer different opportunities.
Regional development efforts, therefore, were to be aimed at these focal
points in slow growth regions in order to start the process of self-sustaining
growth. The benefits, it was assumed, would then radiate outward into
the surrounding areas.
While the establishment
of DREE addressed the need for a coordinated and rationalized federal
effort, it did not deal adequately with the problems of regional disparity.
A major policy review undertaken in 1972 concluded that:
- Regional disparities were too
complex to be dealt with effectively by one government department alone;
a comprehensive approach was required whereby the collectivity of government
policies was made more aware of and sensitive to regional development
objectives.
- Nationally applied programs
were not sufficient and should be complemented by selective and flexible
measures to take advantage of identified development opportunities and
to overcome identified development constraints.
- The policy concern should not
be regional disparities per se but rather encouraging each region
of Canada to realize its potential for economic and social development.
This change in perspective was important, as it indicated a greater
emphasis on potential for development rather than on area problems.
This review led
to a complete alteration in the federal approach to regional development.
While DREE remained the lead federal agent, the "growth poles"
approach was abandoned in favour of a more flexible multi-dimensional
approach involving increasing cooperation between the federal and provincial
governments as well as among the federal departments.
This increasing
cooperation resulted in a set of federal-provincial economic agreements
known at first as the General Development Agreements (GDA), and after
1984 as the Economic and Regional Development Agreements (ERDA). In this
framework, the provinces have a more pronounced role to play in the formulation
and implementation of regional development programs. Central to each ERDA,
are criteria which spell out the framework within which the two levels
of government can work together for the promotion of regional or industrial
growth. The specifics of each ERDA reflect the priorities and concerns
of individual provinces. When joint undertakings are identified, they
are implemented through subsidiary agreements which usually provide for:
i) concrete initiatives to be taken; ii) the level of financial
assistance available; iii) a mechanism of consultation and coordination;
and iv) information sharing between the two levels of government.
Greater flexibility in the design and adoption of subsidiary agreements
is achieved by having federal line departments participate directly at
the subsidiary level.
D.
The Creation of DRIE
In 1982, DREE was
replaced by the Department of Regional Industrial Expansion (DRIE), which
amalgamated the programs of DREE and the Department of Industry, Trade
and Commerce (also disbanded in that year). Federal industrial and regional
incentives were available in one new program -- the Industrial and Regional
Development Program (IRDP), which provided financial assistance to manufacturing,
processing and service industries. While all areas of the country qualified
for assistance, the level of support varied by region and by type of investment
activity.
A 1987 review of
IRDP and ERDA programs by the House of Commons Standing Committee on Regional
Industrial Expansion revealed a consensus in the regions on several aspects
of the operations of DRIE Canada. First, there were complaints that the
programs did not respond to the needs of the regions because these programs
were designed, and applications for funding were evaluated, using standards
that could not be generally applied. Without local input in the process,
it was felt that the wrong kinds of projects were funded and locally worthwhile
proposals were ignored.
A second difficulty
with the DRIE programs was said to be that they attempted to satisfy two
separate objectives: industrial promotion and regional development. To
the less-developed regions, it appeared that DRIE sectoral concerns dominated
the decision-making process and, hence, more funding and assistance were
provided for industrial development than for regional development. The
residents of these regions felt that federal assistance should be made
available for small scale resource-based projects and that the selection
of projects should be carried out by local offices.
E.
The 1987 Restructuring
By the mid-1980s
it was a general believed, in spite of the variety of initiatives implemented
over the preceding decades, that DRIE was not achieving sufficient success
in reducing regional disparities. This concern led to a restructuring
of regional development policies effective in 1987. The principal feature
of the new policy was a decentralization of administrative and policy
functions away from Ottawa and towards the regions. Programs and measures
were to be developed according to the needs of the region they were intended
to assist and would no longer be expected to apply throughout the country.
This new approach would involve more direct interaction between local
federal agencies and the community in the design and implementation of
programs.
Restructuring of
the federal regional development efforts began in the summer of 1987,
when it was announced that DRIE would be disbanded and its industrial
support programs amalgamated with those of the Ministry of State for Science
and Technology to create the Department of Industry, Science and Technology
(IST). The new department would retain responsibility for regional development
in southern Ontario and Quebec, while DRIEs other regional development
responsibilities would be taken over by three regionally based agencies.
The IRDP program was allowed to lapse in June 1988.
The Atlantic
Canada Opportunities Agency (ACOA), coordinates all federal activities
relating to economic development in Atlantic Canada and provides a regional
perspective on the design and application of national policies and programs.
Its original budget was set at $1.05 billion over five years. The Agency
enjoys considerable freedom to adopt whatever measures it feels may best
suit the need of the Atlantic region.
FedNor, an agency
within IST, was established to promote economic development in northern
Ontario and to provide the federal government with local input and advice
on policies, programs and services affecting that region. The agency originally
had a budget of $55 million over five years.
The Department
of Western Diversification (WD), was established to coordinate, support
and encourage the creation of enterprises in the four western provinces
of Canada. It also coordinates the activities of other federal agencies
and departments active in the West. WD was originally endowed with a $1.2-billion
Western Diversification Fund, which was expected to be disbursed over
a five-year period.
In 1991,
federal regional development efforts in the province of Quebec were decentralized
to a new agency, the Federal Office of Regional Development-Quebec (FORD-Q).
Provided with a five-year budget of $1.3 billion, the Departments
objectives were to: define federal objectives pertaining to regional development
in Quebec; negotiate and administer economic development agreements with
the provincial government; and administer support programs for appropriate
initiatives in each region of Quebec.
In a sense, the
creation of ACOA, FORD-Q and WD represents a continuation of the decentralization
of Canadian regional development efforts as recommended in the 1972 review
of DREE. Along with the ERDA programs, the new structure incorporated
a considerable local element into the determination and implementation
of regional development programs, which has resulted in the creation of
different programs in each region.
F.
Summary
Though there have
been marginal successes over the years, more often Canada's regional development
programs have not reduced disparities. Dissatisfactions with the programs
led to periodic reorganizations of federal efforts in this field, many
of which reflected the desire of the various administrations to put their
own mark on regional development policy. Too often regional development
programs have simply sought to create jobs without achieving the necessary
changes in the fundamental structure of the local economies that could
ensure long-term opportunities for growth. Although the creation of new
jobs usually implies that growth has occurred, such growth should not
be confused with economic development. Job creation does not signify any
alteration in a region's future prospects. Economic development on the
other hand, implies a fundamental change in an area's ability to create
wealth. Effective regional development policies should result in such
greater opportunity for self-sustaining growth.
CHRONOLOGY
1957 - Royal
Commission on Canada's Economic Prospects (Gordon Commission) identified
regional development as a separate economic issue.
1960-1966 - Several
regionally differentiated tax measures and support programs were introduced
by the federal government.
1969 - The government
created the Department of Regional Economic Expansion (DREE), which
implemented a regional development policy based on growth pole theory.
1974 - Decentralization
of federal regional development efforts was begun. The General Development
Agreements (GDA) were signed with the provinces.
1982-1983 - DREE
was amalgamated with the Department of Industry Trade and Commerce to
create the Department of Regional Industrial Expansion (DRIE). The
GDA system evolved into the Economic and Regional Development Agreements
(ERDA). The Industrial and Regional Development Program was created
to promote regional development at the same time as industrial expansion.
1987 - The federal
government announced the creation of regionally based development agencies
for Eastern and Western Canada. The Ministry of State for Science and
Technology was merged with the industry support component of DRIE to
form a new department, the Department of Industry, Science and
Technology (IST).
1988 - IRDP was
allowed to lapse.
1991 - The Federal
Office of Regional Development-Québec, (FORD-Q) was created to administer
federal development initiatives in that province.
1995 - The Department
of Industry Act, recognizes the jurisdiction of the Minister of Industry
over the three economic development Agencies: ACOA, WD, and FORD-Q.
SELECTED
REFERENCES
Anderson, F.J.
Regional Economic Analysis: A Canadian Perspective. Harcourt
Brace Jovanovich Canada, Toronto, 1988.
Benedetti,
G.J., and R.H. Lamarche. Shockwaves: The Maritime Urban System in
the New Economy. The Canadian Institute on Research for Regional
Development, Moncton, 1994.
Bradfield, Michael.
Regional Economic Analysis and Policies in Canada. McGraw-Hill
Ryerson, Toronto, 1988.
Careless, Anthony
G.S. Initiative and Response: The Adaptation of Canadian Federalism
to Regional Economic Development. McGill-Queen's University Press,
Montreal, 1977.
Economic Council
of Canada. Living Together: Regional Disparities in Canada. Minister
of Supply and Services, Ottawa, 1977.
Hansen,
Niles. "Regional Development Policies: Past Problems and Future
Possibilities." Canadian Journal of Regional Science, Volume
XIX, No. 1, Spring 1996.
Howland, R.D.
Some Regional Aspects of Canada's Economic Development. Royal
Commission on Canada's Economic Prospects, Ottawa, 1957.
Lithwick, N.
Harvey. "Regional Development Policies: Context and Consequences."
Coffey, William J. and Mario Polèse. Still Living Together: Recent
Trends and Future Directions in Canadian Regional Development. The
Institute for Research on Public Policy, Montreal, 1986, p. 121-155.
Melvin, James
R. "Regional Inequalities in Canada: Underlying Causes and Policy
Implications." Canadian Public Policy. Vol. 13, No. 3, 1987,
p. 304-317.
Organisation
for Economic Co-operation and Development. Regional Problems and
Policies in Canada. OECD, Paris, 1994.
Savoie, Donald,
J. Regional Economic Development: Canada's Search for Solutions.
University of Toronto Press, Toronto, 1986.
*
The original version of this Current Issue Review was published in
November 1988; the paper has been regularly updated since that time.
|