91-2E
FISCAL POLICY IN CANADA:
THE CHANGING ROLE OF THE
FEDERAL AND PROVINCIAL GOVERNMENTS
Prepared by:
Jean Soucy, Economics Division
Marion G. Wrobel, Senior Analyst
Revised 27 March 2000
TABLE
OF CONTENTS
ISSUE
DEFINITION
BACKGROUND
AND ANALYSIS
A. Income
B. Expenditures
1. Total Spending
2. Program
Spending vs. Debt Service Charges
C. Deficits
D. Federal
Transfers to the Provinces
E. The
Harmonized Sales Tax (HST)
PARLIAMENTARY
ACTION
CHRONOLOGY
SELECTED
REFERENCES
FISCAL POLICY IN
CANADA:
THE CHANGING ROLE OF THE FEDERAL AND PROVINCIAL GOVERNMENTS*
ISSUE
DEFINITION
Economic policy is increasingly
being conducted by provincial governments. While monetary policy is exclusively
in the federal domain, fiscal policy is a shared responsibility. Attention
tends to be focused on taxes, spending and deficits at the federal level,
but those at the provincial level are in aggregate just as important.
The federal government supplies a significant amount of the financial
resources of the provincial governments ($25,523 million in cash
transfers in fiscal year 1998-1999, around 15.6% of total provincial government
revenues on a public accounts basis; this amount includes $3,500 million
as a one-time CHST cash supplement paid to a third-party trust.)
The federal government also gives the provinces $13,751 million in
tax points.
This paper examines some
of the prominent trends in provincial and federal fiscal policy since
1975 in order to provide a background against which total fiscal policy
and future federal budgets can be evaluated. This is a companion piece
to three Current Issue Reviews dealing with federal fiscal policy: CIRs
No. 87-2, (Federal Spending), 88-7 (Federal Deficit), and
90-3 (Federal Revenues). The data in this paper for Figures
1 to 5 came from Statistics Canada's National Economic and Financial Accounts
and for Figures 6 to 8 from federal and provincial Public Accounts.
BACKGROUND
AND ANALYSIS
A.
Income
Figure 1 portrays developments
with respect to government income. Prior to 1964, provincial revenues
were less than 80% of those of the federal government. Provincial revenues
grew at a much faster pace than federal revenues over the next decade
and a half; consequently, the ratio of provincial to federal revenues
was 1.28:1 in 1978 (see Figure 1). Over the next three years, federal
income grew rapidly, dropping the ratio to 1.09:1 in 1981. Since then
this ratio has fluctuated between 1.09:1 and 1.26:1.
An examination of the major
tax categories -- direct taxes from persons, direct taxes from corporations,
and indirect taxes -- explains these overall trends. In all three cases,
the provinces have increased their share of tax revenues. The ratio of
provincial to federal direct taxes from corporations increased from 0.33:1
in 1966 to 0.66:1 in 1995. Since 1969, provincial governments have collected
more than half of indirect tax revenues in Canada. The ratio of provincial
to federal indirect taxes rose from 1.01:1 to 1.77:1 in 1998. This trend
was not affected by the introduction in 1991 of the Goods and Services
Tax (GST) at the federal level.
The equivalent ratio
for direct taxes from persons (mostly personal income tax (PIT), a much
more important component of tax revenues) increased from less than 0.30:1
before 1965 to 0.64:1 in 1998. In fact, the provincial share of direct
taxes from persons increased dramatically between 1976 and 1978, when
it reached 75% of the federal share. It fluctuated afterwards in a range
between 0.62:1 and 0.71:1. These
trends are shown in Figure 2.
This dramatic change in
the relative share of direct taxes from persons between 1976 and 1978
was intentional. Under the Established Programs Financing Agreements negotiated
in 1977 between the Government of Canada and the provinces, the federal
government made tax room available to the provinces. As a result, provincial
tax rates rose substantially. These increases were 27% in Manitoba, 28%
in Nova Scotia, 38% in Prince Edward Island, 44% in Ontario, and 48% in
Alberta.
After 1978, the provincial
share of direct taxes from persons declined somewhat and fluctuated. The
reversal of this trend may be due to provincial government responses to
the federal government's income tax reform, which has reduced the reliance
on the personal income tax. Several provinces (Prince Edward Island, New
Brunswick, Saskatchewan and, most notably, Ontario) have used this opportunity
to increase their rates and to add surtaxes as deficit control measures.
The recent moves by New Brunswick and Ontario to reduce income taxes by
10% and by more than 30% respectively will reduce the relative shares
of direct taxes from persons going to those provinces in the latter half
of the 1990s.
Provincial governments now
occupy a very large part of the area of indirect taxes, defined here as
taxes that add to the cost of production. They include retail sales taxes,
motive fuel taxes and other sales taxes at the provincial level, sales
and excise taxes at the federal level, import duties and property taxes.
The sharp rise of the provincial
share of indirect taxes was due primarily to a drop in the general Federal
Sales Tax (FST) from 12% to 9%, while at the same time a number of provinces
increased their retail sales tax rates. For example, from 1976 to 1983,
the retail sales tax was increased by two percentage points in each of
the Atlantic provinces and by one point in Quebec and Manitoba. After
1984, the federal share of taxes increased as the government returned
the general Federal Sales Tax rate to 12% and increased the FST rate on
building materials from 5% to 8%.
The introduction of the
federal Goods and Services Tax (GST) in 1991 was to increase the federal
share of consumption taxes, all other things being equal. There are two
major reasons for this. First, the GST is meant to be revenue-neutral
with respect to a Federal Sales Tax of 13.5%, not the 12% that existed
in the first half of 1989. Second, the GST is to be revenue-neutral in
net terms, not gross terms. Since the tax finances an expanded system
of refundable tax credits, larger gross revenues should be expected. On
balance, though, the impact has been minor due to disappointing GST revenues.
B.
Expenditures
1. Total Spending
In aggregate, the federal
government today spends about the same amount as the provinces. Through
the last half of the 1960s and early 1970s, the provincial share of total
government spending increased steadily. Since that time, the trend has
levelled off (see Figure 3).
2. Program Spending
vs. Debt Service Charges
The real difference between
federal and provincial government spending is revealed in debt service
charges (see Figure 4). Even though the interest rate faced by provincial
governments tends to be higher than that faced by the federal government,
provincial debt service charges are substantially lower. This indicates
a much lower stock of debt held by the provincial government sector, the
result of smaller past deficits. This trend will probably change in the
short term, however. Since the federal government has done well since
1997 achieving a surplus of around $3 billion each fiscal year
and some provinces are still in deficit, the ratio of provincial-federal
debt charges will rise.
From 1966 to 1973, the provincial
share of total debt service charges rose dramatically, after which it
declined until 1981, when it stood at 0.48:1. The provincial share rose
through most of the '80s but subsequently fell sharply from 1988 to 1990,
after which it once again grew rapidly.
The explanation for this
pattern can be found in Figure 5, which looks at annual deficits. In 1965,
the federal government ran a surplus. After that year, the relative importance
of provincial deficits changed dramatically from year to year. From 1975
to 1989, the ratio of provincial deficits to federal deficits averaged
0.13:1, although experiencing large fluctuations. The federal government
was accumulating debt much more rapidly than the provinces, thereby contributing
to relatively higher debt servicing costs. From 1990 to 1993, however,
provincial deficits and the ratio of provincial to federal deficits, increased
significantly, contributing to a rise in the provincial share of debt
service charges. For those years, provincial deficits grew faster than
their federal counterpart. However, they subsequently fell faster than
federal deficits. Recent data show that this trend has changed considerably.
The federal governments last three budgets, including the one for
the fiscal year 1999-2000, have been at least balanced. There is no federal
deficit, though there are still some provincial deficits.
In 1989 and 1990, interest
rates were very high, especially for financial paper with short terms
to maturity. The federal government had been moving to a greater reliance
on short-term securities, especially Treasury Bills, since these typically
yield less than long-term bonds. The irony of this policy is that it had
increased federal borrowing costs because short-term paper had a substantially
higher yield than long-term paper in 1989 and 1990. In addition, the use
of short-term instruments and high annual deficits meant that the federal
government was very susceptible to the increases in interest rates that
occurred in 1989 to 1990. The federal government has now increased the
average term to maturity of its debt. While this will increase borrowing
costs somewhat, it will render them more stable and predictable by making
the federal debt less sensitive to interest rate changes. The share of
interest-bearing debt at fixed rates increased from about 50% in 1992-93
to about 67% in 1998-99.
C.
Deficits
The following discussion
is based on data from federal and provincial Public Accounts. Like
that of the federal government, the fiscal position of the provinces was
impaired significantly by the recession of the early 1980s. The deficit
of both levels of government ballooned after 1982. But whereas the deficits
of provincial governments started to decline immediately after 1983, the
federal deficit continued to grow until 1985. And whereas the federal
decline was relatively small, the provincial decline was more dramatic.
The federal deficit in 1990 was 75% of what it was in 1985, when it peaked,
and almost equivalent to what it was in 1983, when the recession ended.
Total provincial government deficits in 1990 were 32% of the peak level
reached in 1987 and 48% of the level reached in 1983.
In 1992, provincial deficits
increased substantially, largely due to developments in the province of
Ontario, and increased even further the next year. According to the
National Accounts, for the first time since the early 1970s the ratio
of provincial to federal deficits exceeded 0.60:1.
The provincial government
sector has in the past been more apt than the federal government to balance
its budgets in aggregate. Although the decade of the 1980s has also been
characterized by high deficits in the provinces, governments there have
been better able than the federal government to restore some sense of
fiscal prudence.
The aggregate decline in
provincial deficits since 1983 has not been without its reverses. The
total of these deficits increased in 1986 and 1987, due mainly to a dramatic
increase in the deficits of the four western provinces, which in 1985
had been essentially balancing their budgets, yet by 1987 were running
deficits totalling over $6,200 million. The reason for this is clear.
Natural resource prices declined substantially in these years and the
real value of output fell by 5% in 1986 and did not grow in 1987.
The situation in Ontario
was different. From 1983 to 1989, real growth averaged 6.2% per annum,
which is exceptionally high by any standard. Yet, not only was the decline
in the deficit slow over this period, in 1986 the deficit actually doubled
from the previous year. In Quebec, the deficit pattern varied only slightly
from that of Ontario, even though real growth, at an average of only 4.7%
per annum, while very good, was 1.5 percentage points less than in Ontario.
Figures 6 to 8 look at some
recent summary fiscal statistics for Canadian governments; the data are
from the Fiscal Reference Tables issued by the Department of Finance updated
on the basis of recent budgets. Data on Quebec net debt for 1998-99 are
from Scotiabank, Provincial Pulse, 3 December 1999.
One reason that the provinces
have been so much more able than the federal government to control their
deficits in recent years is that they were more able to avoid deficits
in the past. Consequently, in 1999, on average only $1 of every $7.9
of the provinces revenues represented interest charges, but more
than $1 out of every $3.8 of federal revenue did so.
Figure 6 shows government
debt servicing costs for Canada and each province for 1997 compared to
1998, expressed as a proportion of each governments total revenues.
The federal government has by far the greatest debt servicing problem,
as it spends just under 27 cents of every dollar of revenue on interest
payments, more than twice the provincial average. Manitoba, Alberta and
British Columbia pay less than 10 cents of every revenue dollar on interest
costs.
Debt servicing costs give
an indication of the amount of fiscal flexibility a government enjoys.
Provinces such as Manitoba, Alberta and BC use the vast proportion of
their revenues on discretionary spending and hence will theoretically
find it easier to implement fiscal restraint. The job of the federal government
is more difficult as more than one-quarter of its revenues is already
spoken for.
The 1996 federal deficit
equalled 3.5% of GDP. Figure 7 looks at government deficits for fiscal
years 1998 and 1999, expressed as a percentage of GDP. By this measure,
Quebec had the worst performance of any government in 1998, followed closely
by Ontario. In 1999, however, these provinces improved their budgetary
situation, with Quebec even realizing a surplus. Nova Scotia and New Brunswick
offered the worst performances of all the provinces. The budgetary situation
also deteriorated in British Columbia. The federal government maintained
its position in government finances. Federal budgets should continue to
be balanced from now on.
Figure 8 presents government
debt to GDP ratios in 1998 and 1999. The federal government stands out
with a debt to GDP ratio that is twice the provincial average. As one
would expect, governments with higher debt levels face higher debt servicing
costs and this pattern is borne out by a comparison of Figures 6 and 8.
The Ontario government stands out as an apparent anomaly, however. Its
net debt is at the provincial average, but debt-servicing costs are well
above the provincial average. This is due to the Ontario governments
personal income tax cuts that are reducing revenues substantially.
D.
Federal Transfers to the Provinces
The 1990 and 1991 federal
budgets restricted the amount of cash transfers that the federal government
provided to the provinces. In 1990, the federal government announced a
two-year freeze on per capita Established Programs Financing transfers
to the provinces; the 1991 budget extended this freeze for three years.
Canada Assistance Plan payments to non-equalization receiving provinces
would be limited to 5% annual growth for the next five years. These measures
were expected to reduce cash transfers by over $5,000 million in five
years, even though such federal transfers would continue to grow at higher
rates than those for federal program spending.
The provinces could respond
to these federal initiatives by reducing spending or increasing taxes.
The provinces had already been accustomed to a decreasing reliance on
federal cash transfers, which accounted for 23% of provincial revenues
in 1975 but for only 19% of revenues in 1989. More and more, the provinces
were using their own tax measures to raise revenue. If the alternative
to these budgetary measures was to be continued levels of cash transfers
coupled with higher federal taxes, a provincial tax increase would be
equivalent to a conversion of cash transfers into tax transfers. This
was consistent with past developments.
As of 1 April 1996, the
bulk of federal transfers to the provinces were in the form of the Canada
Health and Social Transfer (CHST), a block grant replacing the CAP and
EPF funding but which did not affect equalization. Along with this reform
in structure came a reduction in total provincial entitlements and cash
transfers.
The 1996 budget established
a five-year funding arrangement that froze total entitlements for two
years at the 1997-98 level of $25,000 million and allowed total entitlements
to grow after that at an increasing pace. The 1996 budget also stated
that a floor for cash transfers would be established at $11,000 million.
This was important because the governments ability to enforce the
provisions of the Canada Health Act and the non-residency requirements
for social assistance depended upon a significant federal cash contribution
that could be withheld in the event of non-compliance by a province. The
cash floor has now been increased to $14,500 million. This amount
does not include the CHST cash supplements announced in the two last federal
budgets.
The 1996 budget also indicated
that the federal government had gone some way in addressing the arbitrariness
of the original CHST entitlement allocation. Initially, the entitlement
for each province was set at about 9.5% less than the previous years
entitlement under CAP and EPF. This led to wide variations in per capita
funding. The three non-equalization receiving provinces felt aggrieved
because they had previously been subject to the cap on CAP, which had
severely restricted their access to federal transfers. The federal government
reformed the allocation to reflect population growth, thereby reducing
by about half the initial variation in per capita entitlement.
E.
The Harmonized Sales Tax (HST)
On 1 April 1997, residents of Nova Scotia, New Brunswick
and Newfoundland saw the elimination of the GST and provincial retail
sales taxes. They were replaced by an HST of 15%, applied essentially
to the old GST base. As this new tax was expected to generate substantially
lower revenues for these provinces, the federal government has transferred
almost $1 billion to them as a way of cushioning the transition.
For these three provinces, the new HST constitutes a
harmonization of the federal GST and provincial retail sales taxes into
a new value-added tax that very much resembles the old GST. At the retail
level, consumers and retailers in these provinces now face only one tax,
applied to a common base and administered by only one government.
PARLIAMENTARY
ACTION
Fiscal policy at both levels
of government is usually set at budget time and given legislative authority
through the Parliament of Canada or the legislatures of the various provinces.
The basic framework for federal transfers to the provinces can be found
in a number of federal pieces of legislation. These include: the Federal-Provincial
Fiscal Arrangements and Established Programs Financing Act, 1977;
the Federal-Provincial Fiscal Arrangements and Federal Post-Secondary
Education and Health Contributions Act, 1977, (actually passed in
1983); the Canada Health Act; and the Canada Assistance Plan.
CHRONOLOGY
1975
- The government of Alberta ran a surplus of $39 million, in addition
to the $646 million paid into the recently established Heritage Savings
Trust Fund.
-
A new federal-provincial agreement on Established Programs Financing made
extensive use of tax transfers. Provincial governments increased their
personal income tax rates substantially.
1977
- The Newfoundland budget established the provincial PIT rate at 58% of
basic federal tax, a level significantly higher than in any other province.
1981
- The Nova Scotia budget forecast a deficit more than twice as large as
the previous year's and equal to 20% of projected revenue.
1982
- The Newfoundland budget set the retail sales tax at 12%, significantly
higher than in any other province.
-
The Quebec deficit reached $3,000 million for the first time, an amount
which was exceeded in every year until 1987.
-
The Ontario government extended the base upon which the retail sales tax
was applied, resulting in a substantial increase in revenues.
-
The budget of the government of Saskatchewan forecast a deficit, the first
since 1977.
1987
- The government of Alberta forecast a deficit of $2,100 million, despite
the fact that resource revenues were used as budgetary revenues and not
placed in the Heritage Fund.
-
The Saskatchewan budget noted that the deficit, previously forecast to
be $389 million, would in fact be $1,235 million. That budget called for
the elimination of 2,000 civil service positions.
1988
- Stage I of tax reform was implemented. It generally lowered tax rates
for personal and corporate income, while broadening the base of taxable
income. Some provinces used this opportunity to increase their own rates
of tax. Prince Edward Island increased its PIT rate to 57% from 55%, and
levied a 10% surtax.
-
The province of Quebec announced a generous child subsidy plan which would
pay as much as $3,000 per child to larger families.
April
1989 - The federal budget limited the growth in per capita Established
Programs Financing to the rate of growth of GNP, less three percentage
points.
February
1990 - The federal budget contained an expenditure control plan which
limited transfers to the provinces. Established Programs Financing payments
for fiscal years 1991 and 1992 were limited to their 1990 per capita levels.
For the same years, Canada Assistance Program payments to Ontario, Alberta
and British Columbia were limited to a 5% annual growth rate.
January
1991 - The Goods and Services Tax was implemented as originally planned.
The retail sales tax in the province of Quebec, applying to goods only,
was integrated with the GST.
July
1992 - Services were added to the Quebec base.
April
1997 - The Harmonized Sales Tax at 15% in Nova Scotia, New Brunswick and
Newfoundland would replace the GST and retail sales taxes in those three
provinces.
February-March
2000 - The federal government announced significant tax reductions; most
provinces subsequently did the same.
SELECTED
REFERENCES
Bank
of Canada Review. Ottawa, various issues.
Canada,
Department of Finance. The Budget. Tabled in the House of Commons by the
Honourable Michael H. Wilson, Minister of Finance, Ottawa, 20 February
1990.
Canada,
Department of Finance. Debt Management Strategy - 2000-01. Ottawa,
23 March 2000.
Canadian
Tax Foundation. Provincial and Municipal Finances. Toronto, 1990.
Canadian
Tax Foundation. The National Finances. Toronto, 1990.
Domingue,
Richard. Harmonization of Sales Taxes. Current Issue Review 94-1,
September 1996.
Horry,
I.D. and M.A. Walker. Government Spending Facts. The Fraser Institute,
Vancouver, 1989.
Ip,
Irene K. Big Spenders - A Survey of Provincial Government Finances
in Canada. Policy Study 15, C.D. Howe Institute, Toronto, June 1991.
Perry,
J. H. A Fiscal History of Canada. The Postwar Years. Canadian Tax
Paper No. 85. Canadian Tax Foundation, Toronto, 1989.
Perry,
J.H. Taxation in Canada. Fifth Edition. Canadian Tax Paper No.
89. Canadian Tax Foundation, Toronto, 1990.
Statistics
Canada. Provincial Government Finance. Cat. No. 68207. Annual,
Ottawa, various issues.
Toronto
Dominion Bank. TD Report on Provincial Government Finances. August
1996.
Wrobel, M.G.
Budgets 1996: Continuing Restraint by Federal, Provincial and Territorial
Governments. BP-425, August 1996.
*
The original version of this Current Issue Review was published in
January 1991; the paper has been regularly updated since that time.
|