Government of Canada / Depository Services Program Canada
CCSB Home PWGSC Home DSP Home Who We Are What's New Canada Site Search Help Contact Us Français

Depository Services Program

Parliamentary Research Branch

 

PRB 98-2E

THE WTO, STATE TRADING ENTERPRISES (STEs)
AND EXPORT SUBSIDIES

Prepared by:
Sonya Dakers, Science and Technology Division
Jean-Denis Fréchette, Economics Division
      September 1998


The Uruguay Round of multilateral trade negotiations (MTN), which concluded in 1994, led not only to the creation of the World Trade Organization (WTO) but also to the birth of a new order in world trade. They have served to bring about reductions in export subsidies and domestic support programs, and have promoted greater market access, thanks to introduction of a tariff rate system to replace the varied and complex trade barriers that existed previously. One of the anticipated effects of the new tariff structure is that commercial transactions between countries will become more transparent.

For Canada’s grain trade, the major impact of the MTN has been to eliminate the "Crow rate" system (Western Grain Transportation Act), which was a direct subsidy to grain exports. Since Canada maintains no other export subsidy for grains, and since the domestic support it gives producers is in line with WTO rules, Canada should now in principle be viewed as a fair trading partner; however, this is not the case. After years of attacking the Crow rate, the Americans have now shifted their attention to the Canadian Wheat Board, which is the only remaining target.

Although they did not feature as a major subject of discussion during the last MTN, state trading enterprises such as the CWB were nonetheless subjected to an examination that served to define them more closely, and thus identified more clearly the regulatory framework within which they operate.

What is a state trading enterprise? The 1994 Understanding Concerning the Interpretation of Article XVII of the GATT defined trading enterprises as follows:

Governmental and non-governmental enterprises, including marketing boards, which have been granted exclusive or special rights or privileges, including statutory or constitutional powers, in the exercise of which they influence through their purchases or sales the level or direction of imports or exports.(1)

 

The WTO Secretariat notes that there are 16 member countries where a specialized STE is engaged in the wheat trade. The best known and most important of these are the Australian Wheat Board and the Canadian Wheat Board (CWB). The structure of the latter rests on three pillars — its role as a single-desk seller, its relationship with the federal government, and price pooling. The CWB is the object of regular attacks by the U.S. government. (see Canada-U.S. Grain Trade Relations)

A Canada-U.S. Joint Commission on Grains, created pursuant to the Canada-U.S. Free Trade Agreement (FTA), was mandated to examine the structures for marketing grains between the two countries, and to suggest approaches for resolving grain trade disputes. In its final report, submitted in October 1995, the joint commission concluded that:

  • The CWB does not receive export subsidies from the Canadian government for its pooled marketing operations; the producers assume the cost of marketing grain products sold by the Board.

  • The government-guaranteed initial price, which is set by regulation, is not an export subsidy, since it is applied indiscriminately for grains sold on both the domestic and export markets.

  • Canada is in compliance with Article XXVII of the WTO’s General Agreement, and has notified the Council for Trade in Goods that the CWB is a state trading enterprise.

 

Nevertheless, the Joint Commission stressed that the discretionary pricing policies that the CWB is able to pursue, thanks to its monopolistic position, have the potential for distorting trade. It recommended therefore that the CWB should no longer have this advantage, and that the Board should be [translation] "more at risk of profit or loss in the marketplace or [encouraged] to act as if it were subject to comparable market risks, without excluding recourse to pooling […]."(2)

The Joint Commission’s conclusions did not prevent 18 members of the U.S. Congress from asking the General Accounting Office (GAO), the equivalent of Canada’s Auditor General, to investigate the capacity of STEs in Canada, Australia and New Zealand to create distortions in export markets.

In its June 1996 report, the GAO noted that officials of the USDA had admitted to having no tangible proof that the CWB was violating trade rules. At the same time, however, it mentioned that the CWB’s monopoly position and its relationship with the federal government — in other words, the first two pillars of the CWB — do have the potential to create trade distortions. In effect, the GAO continued the argument put forward by the Canada-U.S. Joint Commission.

The operations of STEs are subject to the agency’s general rules and must in addition obey their own regulations, as clarified during the Uruguay Round. Thus, the CWB must "in its purchases or sales involving imports or exports, act in a manner consistent with the general principles of non-discriminatory treatment set out in the General Agreement for governmental measures affecting imports or exports by private traders."(3)

The CWB of course will sometimes pursue discriminatory pricing policies in various markets, particularly to counter unfair trade practices such as the export subsidies used by competitors. At first glance, it might appear that the CWB is not respecting the WTO rules; however, it should be noted that an addendum to Article XVII specifies that [translation] "the provisions of this article do not prevent a state enterprise from selling a product at different prices on different markets, provided that it acts in this way for commercial reasons, in order to satisfy the play of supply and demand on export markets."

As can be seen, as a state trading enterprise the CWB has a recognized status under the Canada-U.S. Free Trade Agreement, as well as under the WTO. It has nonetheless been a target for the American government, which has announced its intention of putting STEs on the agenda for the next round of multilateral trade negotiations. This approach may stem from the political interests of U.S. pressure groups, who would like to see the United States increase its market share, or may be part of a U.S. strategy to divert attention from its own "Export Enhancement Program" for grains. The fact is that both the United States and the European Union subsidize their grain exports to certain markets. The U.S. has recently replenished the EEP budget, which now amounts to more than U.S.$500 million.

In examining the behaviour of STEs and their capacity to create market distortions, it is important to look beyond their unique position as a domestic monopoly and beyond the government guarantees that they enjoy. Other factors, such as the amount of domestic support, export subsidies and market access — all conditions that make for market strength — can cause distortions just as readily.

Moreover, economic theory demonstrated long ago that a large share of the world market is needed to have any real influence on trade in any product. Is the CWB, which has a 20% share of the world wheat export market, really a sufficiently important player to "control" that market? There is certainly room for doubt, in which case the CWB would be merely a "price taker" on the world market, even if it must be admitted that some studies have contested this position. It is true that the CWB, thanks to its monopoly in the Canadian wheat export market, can practise price discrimination in certain markets, and can exact premiums that would be impossible if other Canadian sellers were competing for the same market share. At the same time, when the CWB comes face to face with competition from producing countries that provide export subsidies, its only defence is to rely precisely on price discrimination. When account is taken of the circumstances in which grains are marketed, where competition is often fierce and where market segmentation and price discrimination are frequently employed, the CWB’s economic behaviour does not appear substantially different from that of the large private companies active in the same sector, except for one significant advantage: the initial payment, followed by a final payment at the end of the crop year, permits the CWB to assume lower risk than a grain company, which has to pay the full price up to delivery.

As a result of Bill C-4, An Act to amend the CWB and to make consequential amendments to other Acts, Canadian grain producers, through the board of directors, will have a significant role in the destiny of the new corporation. Although the CWB will retain its monopoly on wheat and barley that is marketed for export or domestic human consumption, new pricing options, increased flexibility and enhanced cash flow will now be available to farmers. Single desk and price pooling remain pillars of the CWB; however, should the board of directors ever receive the mandate to change the CWB from a marketing agency to a grain company, they could do so under the current legislation.

For many analysts, the days of the CWB as a single-desk agency are now numbered, particularly if the international pressure for further reform of STEs in the next round of multilateral negotiations and the domestic pressure for a dual-marketing agency persist.


(1) World Trade Organization, General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, Article XVII, paragraph 1.a.

(2) Canada-U.S. Joint Commission on Grains, Final Report, October 1995.

(3) World Trade Organization, General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade.