|
BP-47E
THE OPPOSITION IN A
PARLIAMENTARY SYSTEM
Prepared by:
Gerald Schmitz
Political and Social Affairs Division
December 1988
TABLE OF CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION
GOVERNMENT AND OPPOSITION IN
PARLIAMENTARY DEMOCRACIES
THE OPPOSITIONS
ROLE IN CANADA
OPPOSITION
RIGHTS AND RESPONSIBILITIES:
THE CASE OF THE 32nd PARLIAMENT, 1980-1984
NEXT STEPS: OPPOSITION
DURING THE 33rd PARLIAMENT 1984-88
CONCLUSION
THE OPPOSITION IN A PARLIAMENTARY SYSTEM
INTRODUCTION
A situation in which the activity of
politics is devalued is inimical to parliamentary democracy. Parliament, after all, is
fundamentally about debate "rhetoric" in the classical Greek sense
and the transacting of the peoples business in public. It is also about the right to
dissent in a civilized manner. Genuine political opposition is a necessary attribute of
democracy, tolerance, and trust in the ability of citizens to resolve differences by
peaceful means. The existence of an opposition, without which politics ceases and
administration takes over, is indispensable to the functioning of parliamentary political
systems. If these systems are perceived as not working well as being
"seriously overloaded," to quote a distinguished Canadian Opposition Leader, the
Hon. Robert Stanfield it may be the rights of political oppositions which are
immediately and most visibly at stake, but ultimately the threat is to democratic rights
and freedoms generally. The following paper is an attempt to come to grips with the
challenging nature of the oppositions role in Parliament, specifically in the
Canadian context.
GOVERNMENT
AND OPPOSITION IN PARLIAMENTARY DEMOCRACIES
The division between government and
opposition is as old as political democracy itself. In Aristotles Athenian polity
the essence of self-government was that citizens were, in turn, both the rulers and the
ruled. Government could alternate among different groups of citizens, and the minority
could seek to persuade a majority of its point of view by peaceful (i.e., political)
means. In an age of mass politics, direct citizen democracy has been replaced, with rare
exceptions, by representative systems providing for periodic elections. In turn, these
electoral contests are usually dominated by a small number of political parties which
select their own candidates and leaders. What has not changed, however, in our modern
liberal-democratic society is the hallowed principle that government must rest on the
consent of the governed which means, inter alia, that the minority accepts
the right of the majority to make decisions, provided that there is reciprocal respect for
the minoritys right to dissent from these decisions and to promote alternative
policies. With the advent of representative and responsible parliamentary government, the
distinction between "government" and "opposition" has become more
formalized and routinized, but the underlying principles have not changed.
Of course it is not only in British-style
Parliaments that this sort of ongoing legitimate contestation for decision-making power
takes place. Every pluralistic democratic legislature contains both supporters and
opponents of the executive. And, in all parts of the world, these legislatures are
confronted with the problem of "executive dominance" in the face of modern
demands for more and more government services.(1) The
complaint is often heard that because of these pressures legislative politics is
inefficient, ineffective, and in danger of becoming obsolete. Accordingly, we shall look
at some of the countervailing power available to oppositions in legislatures which,
through their heritage in the British Commonwealth, look to the "Westminster
model" of parliamentary democracy for inspiration.
Although one speaks of a
"model," British parliamentary practice has evolved over centuries and still
rests entirely on convention. The emergence of a set pattern of government and opposition
is of comparatively recent origin. There was a time when the subjects thought fit for
parliamentary debate were severely limited, when opposition to the governments
handling of affairs of state could be considered to smack of treason, and hence to be
dangerous. In the 16th and 17th centuries, the Member of Parliament who went beyond
presenting private, local and special grievances or bills, to oppose the Crown, or even to
debate such national issues as the right of succession, foreign policy and religion,
risked imprisonment or worse. Of this period the historian Macaulay commented:
... every man who then meddled with public
affairs took his life in his hand... It was, we seriously believe, as safe to be a
highwayman as to be a distinguished leader of the opposition...(2)
It was not until the 18th century that it
came to be constitutionally accepted that an opposition could be "loyal" across
the whole spectrum of public policy. Nevertheless, one cannot refer to the existence of an
opposition in the modern sense; throughout most of the 18th century not only was there no
disciplined, organized, and ongoing political formation dedicated to opposing the
government, but also the very idea of "faction" or "party" was
disreputable. Since the gradual formation of cohesive Whig and Tory party groups in the
latter part of the 18th century, the term "the Opposition" has been applied
chiefly to the party or parties whose elected members do not support the ministry of the
day and who offer themselves to the voting public, not just as individual candidates, but
as an organized and disciplined alternative government. The actual term "His
Majestys Opposition" was coined during a British debate in 1826 and has been in
use ever since.
With the development of cabinet government
and the rise of political parties, responsible government has come to rely on electoral
strategies in addition to strictly parliamentary ones. The governing party is
"responsible" to the Commons chiefly in that it can be turned out of office and
replaced by another party at the next election. The government must continue to enjoy the
confidence of the House between elections, but, even in minority government situations,
the real test of confidence is not in the daily balance of forces between government and
opposition in the chamber but in the anticipated or threatened electoral contest among the
major parties. As the distinguished Canadian parliamentarian Stanley Knowles put it:
... the opposition should so conduct
itself in Parliament as to persuade the people of the country that it could be an
improvement on the government of the day. No one will deny that our system works best when
there is a change of government at reasonable intervals.(3)
The role of an opposition party, Mr.
Knowles noted, is to check and prod, but ultimately to replace the government
party. Bernard Crick has also described the British House of Commons as the place where a
"continuous election campaign ... is fought."(4)
In Canada in this century, however, Mr. Knowles criterion of "reasonable
intervals" has often been more the exception than the rule. This has led a number of
observers to point out the potential dangers to parliamentary processes of long periods
where one party controls the executive. Because electoral standing is a necessary but not
a sufficient condition of government legitimacy, one must guard against devaluing the
ongoing test of legitimacy which takes place through the intermediary of the legislature
and the legislative opposition.
It is crucial to maintain the distinction
between parliamentary, representative democracy and the sort of direct, plebiscitary
appeal to "the people" which history shows can be made compatible with the most
technocratic and authoritarian forms of government. A vigorous opposition in Parliament
can be the chief bulwark against the temptation to force majeure and bureaucratic
empire. "The people" speak through the "loyal opposition" as well as
the government, through back-benchers as well as Cabinet ministers. There is simply no
substitute for the "checks and balances" which are brought into play in the
representative and watchdog functions performed by ordinary Members of Parliament.(5) Just as members of the upper house are expected to
use it as a chamber of "sober second thought" as well as a guarantor of minority
rights and sectional interests, so, too, members of the opposition in the lower house are
called upon to act as a brake on government haste, to ensure that all legislation receives
the "due process" of parliamentary deliberation, and to see that diverse and
opposing points of view have a chance to be aired and defended.
THE
OPPOSITIONS ROLE IN CANADA
By the British North America Act of
1867 Canada inherited a constitution "similar in principle to that of the United
Kingdom." Responsible cabinet government and the doctrine of the supremacy of
Parliament were thereby entrenched in the Canadian political system. The role of the
opposition in a parliamentary federation such as Canadas is obviously different from
that of congressional representatives in a pluralist federation like the United States,
where legislators exercise considerably more independence and need not take their cue from
the executive branch. Opposition to government proposals in Congress is expressed through
a fluid, often bipartisan coalition. In Canada the parliamentary opposition is much more
structured, and has a more formal status. But it also has to contend with a disciplined
government party which may control the legislature for long periods of time.
Of course the party system as we know it
is here to stay. We cannot go back to Sir John A. Macdonalds day when parties
included a number of "loose fish" and when the government could be defeated by
shifting coalitions of Members in the Commons without resigning. Today the division
between "government" and "opposition," as noted, is highly structured
and runs almost exclusively along party lines.(6) This
does not mean, however, that everything is a fait accompli once the party lines are
decided at election time. (Interestingly, the term "His (or Her) Majestys
Opposition" has been in use in Canada longer than the title "Prime
Minister," an indication of the assured constitutional standing of the former.) The
role of the leader of the Opposition and of the opposition parties is to be as vigilant
and diligent as the members of the government on the other side of the House. This is how
two of Canadas greatest parliamentarians have described the importance of the
legislative opposition:
I submit, therefore, that you do not have
full political democracy, let alone the economic as well as political democracy for which
my party stands, unless you include along with the ingredients that are taken for granted,
such as universal suffrage, the secret ballot and majority rule, a full and unquestioned
recognition of the rights and functions of the opposition to the government of the day.
Only in this way can you protect the rights of minorities; only in this way can you make
sure that the force of public opinion will be brought to bear on the legislative process,
and we are indeed fortunate in Canada to have inherited from the United Kingdom a
parliamentary system of government, the genius of which is the responsibility of the
government to a parliament in which the rights of those who support the government and
likewise the rights of those who oppose it are clearly recognized.
- Stanley Knowles, "The Role of the
Opposition in Parliament," Address to the Empire Club of Canada, Toronto, 21 March
1957.
If Parliament is to be preserved as a
living institution His Majestys Loyal Opposition must fearlessly perform its
functions. When it properly discharges them the preservation of our freedom is assured.
The reading of history proves that freedom always dies when criticism ends. It upholds and
maintains the rights of minorities against majorities. It must be vigilant against
oppression and unjust invasions by the Cabinet of the rights of the people. It should
supervise all expenditures and prevent over-expenditure by exposing to the light of public
opinion wasteful expenditures or worse. It finds fault; it suggests amendments; it asks
questions and elicits information; it arouses, educates and molds public opinion by voice
and vote. It must scrutinize every action by the government and in doing so prevents the
short-cuts through democratic procedure that governments like to make.
- Hon. John G. Diefenbaker, "The Role
of the Opposition in Parliament," Address to the Empire Club of Canada, Toronto, 27
October 1949.
The Hon. Lester B. Pearson, Mr.
Diefenbakers successor as Prime Minister, and frequent victim of the latters
parliamentary skills, was moved to add a few choice words of his own about the adversarial
nature of the House of Commons:
In national politics during the years when
I was in the government, I watched the Opposition perform their duty vigorously and
industriously, with courage and determination. They rightly insisted on their right to
oppose, attack and criticize, to engage in that cut and thrust of debate, so often and so
strongly recommended by those concerned with the vigour and health of Parliament and the
health of democracy. I cannot forbear to add, however, that the application of this
procedure has, in the past, been occasionally resented by those who are cut and thrust at.(7)
When one reads the above it is hard to
conceive of the history of parliamentary control of the executive as a straightforward one
of ossification and "decline," to cite what has become a common lament. One
factor which may account for the prevalence of this pessimistic interpretation is that,
overshadowed by the Cabinets immediate responsibility for "affairs of
state," the work of backbenchers and opposition members does not always receive the
credit it deserves. Yet as J.R. Mallory remarked a few years ago: "... it would not
be an exaggeration to say that practically every significant measure of reform in the last
forty years has been introduced in parliament by a private member, usually, but not
invariably from the opposition."(8) At times it
has been the opposition which has led, especially on social issues, and the government
which has eventually followed. It would, therefore, be an exaggeration to claim that
congressional systems are necessarily much more vigorous and aggressive in a legislative
sense than our own.
Nor should we underrate the virtues of
Parliament as a forum for debate. As Ralph Heintzman has pointed out:
One of the most attractive features of
Parliament, for example, is a powerful symbolic resonance. In addition to its practical
value, the daily confrontation of government and "loyal" opposition in the House
of Commons symbolizes the inner dialogue, the continual sequence of question and answer,
which distinguishes the truly civilized mind and is reflected in the social and public
life of a civil community. Just as a genuinely sound mind does not suppress either of its
two fundamental impulses but listens instead to both, and tries unceasingly to achieve a
synthesis in which their opposition will be reconciled, so too the good society recognizes
that opposing tendencies are not each others enemies but each others partners
instead, and their indispensable complement. They are linked by an educational contract
which is at once the condition and the sign of civilization.(9)
Unfortunately, as everyone knows, this
ideal of civility does not always obtain in parliamentary practice. When debate
degenerates into sterile reflex antogonism the process itself becomes discredited. Part of
the problem comes about when frustration arises because the demands made on Parliament do
not permit it to exercise its representation and surveillance functions properly.
Backbench MPs cannot expect to have a major influence on legislation. But all MPs have the
right to articulate the interests of their constituents, to scrutinize the actions of the
government, and, if in opposition, to present alternative policies to the public. All of
this requires time on the parliamentary agenda time which the government usually
thinks would be better spent proceeding with its legislative program.
Not only is time "one of the most
important commodities in parliamentary politics,"(10)
there is also the presumption that: "The House of Commons is the ordinary scene of
the battle. It is the great public stage at the centre of the national amphitheatre."(11) Accordingly, opposition parties and individual MPs
compete fiercely for time on this stage. The opposition has certainly lost some of its
prerogatives in this regard: for example, "the right to talk out government bills
(closure, 1913), to filibuster (a limit on individual debate, 1927), to extend
indefinitely major debates (1955), and to appeal the rulings of the Speaker (1965)."(12) The length of speeches has been considerably
shortened and in 1969 closure was used to pass a complicated Standing Order (75 A, B and
C) setting out the procedure to be followed to impose "time allocation" on
debate, either unilaterally or with the consent of one or more opposition parties.
Nonetheless, the opposition still has numerous opportunities to confront the government:
in the daily Question Period, in the eight days of debate following the Speech from the
Throne and in the six days following the Budget and the 25 "opposition days"
scattered throughout each session. The opposition, moreover, has benefited a great deal
from the increased allowances for secretarial and research staff granted to each Member
and to each party caucus,(13) as well as from
expanded facilities such as those of the Library of Parliament. Lacking the resources of
government, opposition members have a vital stake in the continued improvement of services
to parliamentarians.
The question remains how the opposition
can make best use of the parliamentary time available to it. For example, the evidence
suggests that control remains weak over the public purse. MPs are expected to oversee the
governments spending plans through the scrutiny of departmental estimates which are
referred to the appropriate standing committees around the start of each fiscal year. But,
even with the current expanded and reformed committee system, changes are very rarely
attempted to the governments supply bills and expenditure plans.(14) A variety of proposals have been suggested to involve MPs in a
more meaningful way in the polity and expenditure management process, since by itself the
Public Accounts Committee is able to exercise only a post-audit function. Most of these
proposals involve increasing the power and independence of parliamentary committees. But,
as Thomas Hockin has noted, there is bound to be some ambivalence on both sides of the
House about such reforms:
Neither the Government nor the Opposition
has a vested interest in asserting its patrimony over all of the results of the committee
system... Some Opposition MPs wonder if the role of the Opposition in committees does not
sometimes become too collegial, in that Government and Opposition MPs may simply end up
doing little more than tidying up a ministers bill. Not surprisingly, therefore,
some Opposition MPs feel not enough partisan advantage is gained from all this work.(15)
There is at least an implicit conflict
between the notion of MPs as legislators acting in concert with a common purpose, and
their expected partisan roles based on adversarial representation. As Hockin points out,
however, the genius of the parliamentary process is that adversary politics is not simply
negative, but can itself be an important part of the shaping of government policy. Indeed,
without good opposition, policy consensus would be a meaningless formality. Parliament
could not do its work without the techniques of advocacy, contestation and persuasion
pursued by the party caucuses and by individual members. Concludes Hockin:
To choose adversary propaganda politics
instead of collegial coalescent politics may not be without effect on policy in the long
run.
In fact, it can be suggested further that
Opposition parties pursue at least four fundamental representational, yet partisan, roles
in their activity in the House of Commons. Regardless of the nature of the party, all
Opposition parties use the Canadian House as a public forum first to check on the
Governments integrity. They are in constant pursuit of evidence not only of
Government misspending of funds but of wider examples of dishonesty and arbitrary
behaviour. Second, the Opposition prods the Government to act on behalf of certain
interests, opinions and needs in society. Third, the opposition probes for information and
although it seldom has success in eliciting hard information from the Government during
the oral question period, it can be remarkably effective (if it works at it) in eliciting
such information in written questions and in committees. Fourth, the opposition attempts
to re-interpret the Governments interpretation... These functions of the Opposition
parties, when combined with surreptitious efforts by backbench Government MPs to influence
the cabinet, help one to understand more comprehensively the general role of the House of
Commons in the political and policy process in Canada.(16)
That having been said, even if these
parliamentary mandates were to become more clearly appreciated by the Canadian public,
opposition parties would still face some formidable challenges. In particular, when major
decisions take place without passing through parliamentary channels, the opposition is
placed at a distinct disadvantage in terms of its ability to scrutinize and influence
government actions. Increased resort to extra-parliamentary means to resolve the
countrys problems (e.g., federal-provincial conferences, interest group
consultations, etc.) leads inevitably as well to a greater prominence for
extra-parliamentary forms of opposition. To be fully credible as an institution,
Parliament must be able to demonstrate an active presence across the full range of
national public policy concerns. Obviously, in this regard, one should not look
automatically to government, preoccupied as it is with the business of state, for
leadership in strengthening legislative surveillance. The burden of making Parliament more
effective falls, above all, on the shoulders of the opposition and Members of Parliament
in their individual capacities.
OPPOSITION
RIGHTS AND RESPONSIBILITIES:
THE CASE OF THE 32ND PARLIAMENT, 1980-1984
The first session of the first
Parliament of the 1980s set a number of seemingly unenviable precedents which tested the
stamina of both the government and the opposition. The session was the longest on record
(approximately 400 sitting days), not least because of several episodes in which the
opposition, as a last resort, employed tactics in order to block the normal course of
parliamentary business. Yet in the end, the session gave birth to a new Canadian
constitution as well as many major pieces of legislation. From the point of view of the
future role of the opposition, it is important to assess how Parliament acquitted itself
under the strain of these extraordinary circumstances.
Parliamentary reform rose to the top of
the agenda in Canada in the late 1960s, largely as a result of the frustrating experience
with successive minority governments and the exceedingly long and acrimonious debate over
the adoption of a national flag.(17) However, the
reform process itself became so vexed that eventually the government imposed a series of
changes over the strenuous objections of the opposition, to streamline the rules of
debate. Then as later, some critics questioned the use of reform, since, after all,
"the function of Parliament as a whole is to ventilate, not to legislate."(18) Still, most interested observers continued to
believe strongly that Parliament had to be more than just a place for fruitless
"ventilation." In the wake of the bitter debates of the 1980-82 session, a
special Commons committee was established with a mandate to review the standing orders and
procedures of the House and to suggest further reforms.
During 1982 and 1983 the Lefebvre
committee produced a series of innovative reports. One of the most notable early
recommendations to be accepted was the automatic referral of reports from government
departments and agencies to the relevant Commons standing committees, and the requirement
for a substantive government response to committee reports. Sweeping proposals in later
reports to increase the scrutiny of expenditures made little headway. But in a number of
other areas election of the Speaker, broadening the composition of the Board of
Internal Economy, the use of legislative committees whose Chair would be drawn from a
panel of Members chosen by the Speaker from both sides of the House the work of the
special committee in enhancing the role of Private Members of all parties was not in vain
as these reforms were revived and adopted during the 33rd Parliament.
How much these institutional changes
benefited the opposition is open to question, since some of them, such as shortening the
length of speeches, were designed to make the work of Parliament more efficient and
expeditious. Nor did the changes address the continued rigid operation of party
discipline, which put the onus of holding the government to account squarely on the
ingenuity and procedural arsenal of the opposition parties and their parliamentary
leadership.(19) As Van Loon and Whittington have
observed:
In a majority government situation, the
basic strengths and weaknesses of the opposition parties in parliament are determined
primarily by the procedures of the House of Commons. Since they are never going to be able
to outvote the government on any policy proposal, the opposition parties must content
themselves with using subtler techniques to attempt to influence policy.(20)
Two major confrontational incidents drawn
from the first session of the 32nd Parliament showed the lengths to which a determined
opposition could go, although some might dispute the "subtlety" of the
strategies employed. In the first incident, the opposition successfully prevented the
government from moving time allocation on debate on third reading of its constitutional
resolution. By raising a steady stream of points of order and questions of privilege,
House business was interrupted (with two agreed-upon exceptions) from
26 March 1981 until 8 April when the Government House Leader tabled a complex
special motion. This represented a compromise which both guaranteed the government an
eventual conclusion to the debate and conceded the oppositions point that the
conclusion should be delayed until after the Supreme Court had ruled on the
constitutionality of the resolution before the House. In the second incident, the
opposition balked at a multi-purpose omnibus bill (C-94, the Energy Security Act)
introduced by the government as part of its controversial National Energy Program. By
refusing to answer the bells summoning Members to a recorded vote on a related adjournment
motion, the official opposition held up House proceedings while the division bells rang
from 4:20 p.m., 2 March 1982 until 2:28 p.m., 17 March. The logjam was broken by
an all-party agreement to split the bill into eight separate Acts, all of which were
subsequently passed with limited debate.
In the above case, the opposition achieved
a partial victory in its stand against the omnibus nature of a major bill. It is rather
more difficult to say how much was gained in terms of public comprehension and scrutiny of
the complex energy legislation by the attention accorded the sensational bellringing
episode. There was some opposition disappointment that the media coverage did not extend
very far into the substance of the legislation.(21)
This might have been less of a problem had the issues at stake been simple and clear cut.
In the final analysis, the opposition had at least made its point and asserted its rights,
while at the same time the government achieved most if not all of its objectives.
The balance between compromise and
obstruction, co-option and reflex opposition, is often in the eye of the beholder. In the
bitterly contested 1980-82 session referred to above, the government risked opposition
wrath by invoking the guillotine rule (75C) a total of eight times. Several special orders
incorporating time allocation were also passed with respect to constitutional and energy
matters after repeated head-on collisions had exhausted both sides of the House. As the
rules were stretched, anger and mistrust were the inevitable by-products; but once time
pressures came into play and public opinion was mobilized, both government and opposition
relented. Ultimately, a good deal was accomplished. The constitutional resolution was
improved, however arduously, at each stage in the journey toward patriation of the
Constitution. Many key pieces of legislation were passed after substantial amendment. Some
committees were very active and a number of special parliamentary task forces produced
highly regarded reports. In short, the 32nd Parliament was far more productive than public
cynicism or confusion might suggest.
NEXT
STEPS: OPPOSITION DURING THE 33RD PARLIAMENT 1984-88
Although the election of September 1984
left the opposition caucuses smaller and weaker than in the previous Parliament, one of
the first initiatives of the Mulroney government was to set up a special committee on
House of Commons reform, with the avowed intention of giving more clout to backbench MPs.
The McGrath committee tabled its first report in December 1984 and continued its work
until tabling a major final report in June 1985. As a result of the committees
recommendations, changes to the Standing Orders were made on a provisional basis in June
1985 and February 1986. In June 1987 the entire reform package, with slight additions and
modifications, was made permanent.(22)
Among the rule changes of potential
benefit to opposition members (and as well in some cases to independent-minded government
backbenchers) were: election of the Speaker by secret ballot of all Members, provision for
three opposition representatives on the Board of Internal Economy; establishment of ad hoc
legislative committees chaired by members of a panel chosen by the Speaker from Private
Members on both sides of the House; increased committee scrutiny of delegated legislation
with the possibility of disallowance; committee review of Governor in Council appointments
(with, however, no power of rejection); provision for the Leader of the Opposition to
extend by an additional ten sitting days the time available to one standing committee for
studying the estimates; new procedures for Private Members business to allow
"that at any time in the projected order of business there can be up to six motions
and bills which are designated by a new Standing Committee on Private Members
Business to be votable"(23); more
autonomy for 25 established standing committees, with the power to initiate their own
investigation and study references, along with increased staff support and larger budgets
allocated by a liaison committee of all chairs, subject to the approval of the Board of
Internal Economy.
The McGrath Committee also recommended a
significant relaxation of party discipline so that only very rarely would House votes be
regarded explicitly as matters of "confidence," whose defeat would bring down
the government. However, entrenched attitudes and habits have proved hard to break. The
33rd Parliament was not noticeably less partisan or adversarial than the one which
preceded it, to the chagrin of those impatient for further reform.(24) Moreover, some of the new rules, such as the provision for
standing committee review of Cabinet appointments, were not used to much effect. Above
all, because of the number of committees, both standing and legislative, new and old,
opposition resources were often stretched to the limit. The larger opposition caucuses in
the 34th parliament should at least solve that problem.
In contrast to the numerical weakness of
the official opposition in the House of Commons, members of its caucus held a strong
majority in the Senate. The renewed activism of senators in opposition provoked several
protracted confrontations with the government, notably over bills on borrowing authority,
pharmaceutical patents, refugee determination and, finally, implementation of the
Canada-U.S. Free Trade Agreement. The government several times threatened action to take
away the Senates power to defeat bills. However, the Senate had some success in
obtaining amendments to several important bills, and by agreeing to stand its ground on
passage of the free trade bill, it allowed the opposition parties in the last election to
campaign against the trade agreement as not yet being a fait accompli. Meanwhile,
the proposal for Senate reform had been largely taken out of the partisan arena of the
Commons by being tied to the fate of the Meech lake Constitutional Accord.
CONCLUSION
To sum up, developments during the last
two Parliaments have had a mixed impact on the fortunes of political oppositions in
Canada. The major overhaul of House of Commons rules, begun in 1982 and completed in 1987,
and the renewed activism of the Senate after 1984, have provided new opportunities for
opposition members to contribute to the policy process, at least at the margins. The
presence of television cameras in the Commons and the possible expansion of electronic
coverage to committee hearings are also innovations which offer advantages to a skilled
opposition. At the same time, some of the procedural reforms, such as the streamlining of
debates and the taking of votes, primarily aid the government by making it harder for
opposition parties to sustain the use of dilatory or obstructionist tactics. Moreover, the
opposition must be careful that in resorting to time-wasting devices and theatrical
outbursts in Question Period it is not creating an unfavourable impression of Parliament
among the general public.
The two parliamentary oppositions in
Ottawa must also consider their role in relation to other extra-parliamentary
circumstances and forms of political opposition. Our electoral system frequently results
in sharp regional imbalances in the parties caucus representation, in a high
electoral casualty rate for caucus dissidents and independents, and in the exclusion of a
growing number of minor or so-called "fringe" parties from parliamentary life. A
significant number of Canadians probably feel that their views are not adequately
represented in the ranks of either the government or the opposition. At the same time,
non-party protest and lobby groups have become increasingly active at all stages of the
political process. In constitutional matters, the major oppositional roles now tend to be
played by provincial governments and legislatures. The opposition caucuses, therefore,
cannot just fix their confrontational gaze on the government benches; they must also look
over their shoulders at other under-represented or competing groups, with at times louder
voices, in the arena of national politics.
As a recent text observes:
... many of the difficulties encountered
by the opposition in formulating effective criticism of government policy have less to do
with House of Commons procedures or research facilities than with more fundamental
problems which also afflict parliamentary oppositions in the other western democracies.
One is that the official Opposition in Parliament often has difficulty in making itself
heard above the "hubbub" coming from other political actors. Major interest
groups and private research institutes frequently offer articulate and well-publicized
criticisms of government policy, and, in a federal context such as Canada, "there is
little doubt that the clashes between the provinces and the federal government ... detract
attention from the federal parliamentary opposition on some of the most important issues
in Canadian politics."
Sometimes, too, it may be difficult for
the opposition parties to offer clearcut alternatives to government policy. Some issues do
not lend themselves to a confrontational style of politics, since they cut across party
lines and strain party cohesion on both sides of the House. This is especially true of
moral issues such as abortion, capital punishment or nuclear weapons. On other social and
economic policy issues, the development of an ideological consensus supportive of the
mixed-economy and the welfare state in most western societies has tended to preclude the
presentation of radical policy alternatives by a "loyal" opposition.(25)
Parliament exists not only to transact the
business of state, but to provide a forum in which all legitimate points of view can be
expressed. The government has a right and duty to govern. The oppositions right and
duty, if it believes the public interest is at stake, is to oppose the governments
policies and actions by every legitimate parliamentary means. In so doing, oppositions try
to convince the electorate that they should change places with the government. Because of
this continuous contest, parliamentary democracy is always a more or less trying affair,
but politics, not mere administration, is what representative, alternative government is
all about.
The debate about the respective roles of
governments and oppositions is not a new one. Today, however, the development of state
institutions, and the expanding horizon of state activities tend to contrast unfavourably
with the relative "underdevelopment" of legislative controls over the executive
branch. This has directed attention to the factors impinging on the effective operation of
"checks and balances" in democratic political systems, and, in turn, to numerous
proposals for legislative reform.(26) In
parliamentary systems there is a fundamental constitutional principle of responsible
government at stake. And in the Canadian case, the tradition of one-party government,
combined with the frequent weakness of legislative oppositions, poses added dangers.(27)
Under these circumstances, preserving and
enhancing the role of the opposition becomes critical to the democratic legitimacy of the
system as a whole. With rare exceptions, government backbenchers cannot hold the Cabinet
and civil service to account. It is the opposition which is chiefly responsible for
keeping government on its toes, and for fearlessly asserting the rights of the legislature
vis-à-vis the executive. By performing these duties the opposition is really doing
everyone a favour because, as John Stewart has noted: "slipping things through the
house may seem smart in the short run. In the long run it works to discredit both the
government and parliament."(28) However much
the classical model of Parliaments may be said to have waned in favour of a Parliament
based on administrative convenience,(29) the best
guarantee of good government is still the vigilance of an effective parliamentary
opposition.
(1)
See, for example, David Olson, The Legislative Process: A Comparative Approach,
Harper & Row, New York, 1980, esp. ch. 1. The changing balance of forces in political
society is also the subject of numerous articles in the international comparative politics
journal Government and Opposition. Its Autumn 1988 issue contained an article by
George Feaver, "Letter from Canada" which surveyed Canadian political
developments since 1968.
(2) Cited in Thomas
Hockin, "The Role of the Loyal Opposition in Britains House of Commons: Three
Historical Paradigms," Parliamentary Affairs, Vol. 25, 1971-72, p. 54.
(3) Stanley Knowles,
"The Role of the Opposition in Parliament," Address to the Empire Club of
Canada, 21 March 1957, Ontario Woodsworth Memorial Foundation, Toronto, 1957.
(4) Bernard Crick, The
Reform of Parliament, Weidenfeld and Nicolson, London, 1954, p. 95.
(5)
Empirical research strongly supports the view that legislatures are more responsive to the
public than other branches of government. The role of legislators cannot be usurped by
government functionaries. See, for example, Lee Sigleman and William Vanderbok,
"Legislators, Bureaucrats and Canadian Democracy: The Long and the Short of it,"
Canadian Journal of Political Science, Vol. 10, 1977, p. 615-23.
(6)
Cf. Eugene Forsey, "Government Defeats in the Canadian House of Commons,
1867-73," Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, XXIX:3, August
1963, p. 364-67; and Thomas Hockin, "Flexible and Structured Parliamentarianism: From
1848 to Contemporary Party Government," Journal of Canadian Studies, 14:2,
Summer 1979.
(7)
"The Role of the Opposition," Address to the Canadian Club of Ottawa, 27 January
1959.
(8)
Cited in Allan Kornberg and William Mishler, Influence in Parliament: Canada, Duke
University Press, Durham, N.C., 1976, p. 56.
(9)
Ralph Heintzman, "The Educational Contract," editorial introduction to the Journal
of Canadian Studies, special issue on "Responsible Government Reconsidered,"
Vol. 14, No. 2, Summer 1979, p. 143.
(10)
C.E.S. Franks, "Procedural Reform in the Legislative Process," in William A.W.
Neilson and James C. MacPherson, eds., The Legislative Process in Canada, Institute
for Research on Public Policy and Faculty of Law, University of Victoria, 1978 p. 250.
(11)
John Stewart, The Canadian House of Commons, cited by Geoffrey Stevens in ibid.,
p. 230.
(12)
Robert Jackson and Michael Atkinson, The Canadian Legislative System, 2nd rev. ed.,
Macmillan, Toronto, 1980, p. 117.
(13)
The official opposition and its leader have added standing, such as priority in some
debates and in Question Period, as well as the use of an official residence. For a party
caucus to be recognized, it must have a minimum of 12 members, although this requirement
may be relaxed if there are special circumstances.
(14)
See Harold D. Clarke, et al., eds., Parliament, Policy and Representation,
Part II, esp. Paul Thomas, "Parliament and the Purse Strings," p. 160-181.
(15)
Hockin, "Adversary Politics and Some Functions of the Canadian House of
Commons," in O. Kruhlak et al., eds., The Canadian Political Process
(1979), p. 370. See also C.E.S. Franks, "The Dilemma of the Standing Committees of
the Canadian House of Commons," Canadian Journal of Political Science, Vol. 4,
1977, p. 461-476
(16)
"Adversary Politics and Some Functions of the Canadian House of Commons," p.
377-78.
(17)
For an early discussion of the problem see Pauline Jewitt, "The Reform of
Parliament," Journal of Canadian Studies, Vol. 1, No. 3, November 1966, p.
11-15; also Trevor Lloyd, "The Reform of Parliamentary Proceedings," in Abraham
Rotstein, ed., The Prospect of Change: Proposals for Canadas Future,
McGraw-Hill, Toronto, 1965.
(18)
J.A. Lovink, "Who Wants Parliamentary Reform?" Queens University,
Vol. 79, 1972, p. 510.
(19)
The pattern of formalized partisan jockeying in terms of government and opposition holds
equally true for provincial legislatures. Cf. the conclusions in Frederick Fletcher and
Arthur Goddard, "Government and Opposition: Structural Influences on Provincial
Legislatures," Legislative Studies Quarterly, Vol. III, No. 4, November
1978, p. 647-69.
(20)
Richard Van Loon and Michael Whittington, The Canadian Political System: Environment,
Structure and Process, 3rd ed., McGraw-Hill Ryerson, Toronto, 1981, p. 62.
(21)
Given the selective reporting of House activities, and particularly committee proceedings,
opposition critics may be inclined to agree with a remark of Oscar Wilde on returning from
the première of one of his plays: "... the play was a success but the audience was a
failure." (Quoted in Hockin, "Adversary Politics and Some Functions of the
Canadian House of Commons," (Kruhlak) (1979), p. 372.)
(22)
For a complete review of these changes see Library of Parliamentary Research Branch
Current Issue Review #82-15E, House of Commons Procedure: Its Reform; also Charles
Robert, "Changing the Rules of the Game in the Canadian House of Commons," The
Table, Vol. LV, 1987, p. 128-37.
(23)
Nora Lever, "Whats Happened under the New Rules?" Canadian
Parliamentary Review, Autumn 1988, p. 14. In the last House, one "votable"
bill proposed by an opposition member, Lynn McDonald, - Bill C-204, the Non-smokers
Health Act received Royal Assent on 28 June 1988.
(24)
See David Kilgour, "Party Discipline and Canadian Democracy," Canadian
Parliamentary Review, Autumn 1988, p. 10-11.
(25)
Robert Jackson, Doreen Jackson and Nicolas Baxter-Moore, Politics in Canada: Culture,
Institutions, Behaviour and Public Policy, Prentice-Hall Canada, Scarborough, 1986, p.
332.
(26)
See, for example, Robert Dahl, "Patterns of Opposition," in Dahl, ed., Political
Oppositions in Western Democracies, Yale University Press, New Haven, 1966; The
Role of the Legislature in Western Democracies, American Enterprise Institute for
Public Policy Research, Washington, 1981; Thomas dAquino et al., Parliamentary
Democracy in Canada: Issues for Reform, Business Council on National Issues, Ottawa,
1983, especially p. 32-6 on "The Role of the Opposition: Tactics, Information and
Accountability."
(27)
The disjunction between the pattern of executive growth and the powers of the legislature
has been especially common in provincial political systems. Alberta has a long history of
weak legislative oppositions. Currently there are no opposition members in the New
Brunswick legislature.
(28)
John Stewart, "Strengthening the Commons," Journal of Canadian Studies,
special issue on "Responsible Government Reconsidered," Summer 1979, p. 47.
(29)
Often cited are the desire of modern governments for functional "efficiency,"
their reluctance to divulge information, and the tendency towards the use of executive
orders and regulatory powers whenever possible.
|
|