|
87-2E
FEDERAL SPENDING:
CHANGING TRENDS
Prepared by:
Jean Soucy, Economics Division
Marion G. Wrobel, Senior Analyst
Revised 27 March 2000
TABLE
OF CONTENTS
ISSUE
DEFINITION
BACKGROUND AND ANALYSIS
A. Spending Trends
B. Spending on Social
Services
1. Old Age
Security and Related Programs
2.
The Seniors Benefit
3.
(Un)Employment Insurance
4. Family Allowances/Child
Tax Benefits
C. Debt Charges
D. Federal
Budgets of 1990, 1991 and 1992 and
the December
1992 Economic Statement
E. The 1993 Federal Budget
F. The 1994 Federal Budget
G. The 1995 Federal Budget
H. The 1996 Federal Budget
I. The 1997 Federal Budget
J. The 1998 Federal Budget
K. The 1999 Federal Budget
L. The 2000 Federal Budget
PARLIAMENTARY ACTION
CHRONOLOGY
SELECTED REFERENCES
FEDERAL SPENDING:
CHANGING TRENDS*
ISSUE DEFINITION
Since 1970-71, total
federal government expenditures have increased from $16,000 million to
about $158,000 million. To put this in perspective, they went from 18%
of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) in early 1970-71, to 15.8% of GDP in 2000-2001.
These data, however, hide the fact that federal spending had grown to
about 25% of GDP by the mid 1980s, from when it has declined (Figure 1).
The longer-term trend in
spending originated many decades ago. This paper is concerned with only
the more recent growth and explores not so much the aggregate level of
expenditures as changes in the various components of spending. It will
examine those components which account for total expenditure growth and
explain why they do so.
BACKGROUND AND ANALYSIS
A. Spending
Trends
The following three charts
summarize trends in federal spending. Figure 1 looks at total spending
as a proportion of GDP and provides a reference point by including revenues.
We see a very pronounced trend to increased federal spending through the
1970s and first half of the 1980s. Since then, spending has fallen dramatically.
The chart clearly
shows the effects of recessions on spending. Nevertheless, the first 15
years show a clear trend towards higher spending, which was reversed in
the latter 17 years portrayed in the chart. Spending as a proportion
of GDP is lower today than it was in the early 1970s.
While
total spending has gone up and down, its composition has changed steadily.
Since the mid 1970s, when the debt-to-GDP ratio reached its lowest level,
the proportion of total spending accounted for by debt service charges
has trebled, from 10% of total spending to about 30%. The budgetary
projections suggest that debt service charges will stabilize at about
26% of spending, as can be seen in Figure 2.
Figure 3 presents five
major components of program spending and shows them as a proportion of
total program spending. Trends over time for these categories give
some indication of changes in government priorities. The chart shows a
slow but steady move away from government funding of Crown corporations.
There is a similar trend with respect to defence spending; the relative
share of program spending devoted to defence has fallen by over 25% since
1990. Other departments and agencies account for an increasing share
of spending, which should rise to 21.4% by fiscal year 2001-2002.
Transfers to other governments
now constitute the third largest category of spending, according to this
chart. Such transfers continued to have a relatively steady share
of program spending until the introduction of the CHST. Since then,
their share has declined; by fiscal year 2001-2002, it should account
for just under 20% of program spending.
Transfers to persons are
the most important component of federal spending, comprising just under
30% of program spending in the latter half of the 1980s. This grew to
over 34% as a result of the recession and greatly increased Unemployment/Employment
Insurance benefits. EI reforms caused the cost of benefits to fall
somewhat so that transfers to persons should account for 31.1% of program
spending by fiscal year 2001-2002.
The small increase in the
relative importance of transfers to persons to the year 2002 is partly
due to demographic changes causing steady growth in benefits to seniors.
More important, however, the increase is due to the fact that these transfers
were largely immune to the cutting applied to other programs. With the
exception of EI reforms, which had their main effect prior to 1996, there
have been no cuts to transfers to individuals in the latter half of the
decade. Thus the relative importance of this category is growing slightly
by default.
B.
Spending on Social Services
In fiscal year 1986-87,
the federal government spent $41,711 million on social services, as defined
by Statistics Canada. The expenditures grew by 3.7% over the previous
fiscal year. Over three years to 1986-87, social service expenditures
increased by almost 20%. These expenditures constitute the major part
of program spending and as such are a good subject for additional scrutiny.
In addition, as a number of them were (and still are) subject to automatic
indexation through much of the 1970s and early 1980s, they provide a convenient
area to test the assertion that indexation has contributed to the rapid
growth of government expenditures.
The two most significant
programs are old age security payments and employment insurance. Gross
expenditures on the OAS system are currently in the $24,200 million
range and expenditures on EI amount to $11,500 million. Prior
to reform of the Child Benefit System, the amounts spent on family allowances,
though smaller, were also important.
Federal spending on social
security in 1988 amounted to $45,335 million, compared to $4,497 million
in 1970. Spending grew 14.6% faster than average in Newfoundland, while
it grew about 14% less than average in Saskatchewan. In Ontario, spending
increased 10% less than the national average. These provincial variations
are due to differences in population growth, income growth and demographic
change. As shown in Table 1, total government transfers for 1999
have considerably been increased. This increase is due to the $3.5 billion
one-time supplement to the CHST announced as an immediate measure to help
provincial governments with their health care programs. In 2000, another
one-time supplement of $2.5 billion was announced.
1. Old Age Security
and Related Programs
The Old Age Security (OAS)
provides a universal taxable benefit to anyone over the age of 65 who
meets certain residence requirements. This benefit is indexed quarterly
to changes in the Consumer Price Index. It has been indexed, off and on,
to the rate of inflation since 1971. The OAS is complemented by two other
programs for the elderly: Guaranteed Income Supplement (GIS) and the Spouse's
Allowance (SPA). These programs put to rest the myth that selectivity
necessarily reduces program cost. Although the system has become more
selective, it has also become more generous and thus more expensive.
After 1952, the system of
old age pensions was completely universal; however, with the introduction
of the GIS, it is becoming increasingly selective. This becomes clear
if we consider the relationship between the maximum OAS and GIS rates.
In 1971 the GIS maximum was 69% of the OAS payment. By 1987 it reached
119% of the OAS rate, where it remains today. Put another way, the OAS
payments have stayed relatively constant since 1971; when measured in
real dollars, they have increased by only 13%, while the maximum GIS rate
has more than doubled.
TABLE 1
SOME FEDERAL SPENDING STATISTICS
(in million dollars)
Fiscal
Year
(ending
31 March)
|
Total
Spending
|
Program
Spending
|
Gross
Debt
Charges
|
National
Defence
|
Transfers:
Persons
|
Transfers:
Governments
|
1970-71
|
15,998
|
14,111
|
1,887
|
1,818
|
3,281
|
2,954
|
1971-72
|
18,405
|
16,295
|
2,110
|
1,862
|
3,942
|
3,610
|
1972-73
|
21,107
|
18,807
|
2,300
|
1,937
|
5,153
|
4,134
|
1973-74
|
24,641
|
22,076
|
2,565
|
2,224
|
6,042
|
4,585
|
1974-75
|
31,476
|
28,238
|
3,238
|
2,526
|
7,620
|
5,884
|
1975-76
|
37,862
|
33,892
|
3,970
|
2,966
|
9,233
|
6,874
|
1976-77
|
41,304
|
36,596
|
4,708
|
3,373
|
9,873
|
8,399
|
1977-78
|
45,505
|
39,974
|
5,531
|
3,776
|
11,104
|
8,512
|
1978-79
|
50,004
|
42,980
|
7,024
|
4,096
|
12,030
|
9,551
|
1979-80
|
53,996
|
45,502
|
8,494
|
4,377
|
11,967
|
10,601
|
1980-81
|
63,423
|
52,765
|
10,658
|
5,063
|
13,793
|
11,578
|
1981-82
|
75,981
|
60,867
|
15,114
|
5,672
|
16,051
|
13,088
|
1982-83
|
89,711
|
72,808
|
16,903
|
6,599
|
21,697
|
14,177
|
1983-84
|
97,045
|
78,968
|
18,077
|
7,679
|
22,514
|
17,125
|
1984-85
|
109,493
|
87,100
|
22,393
|
8,636
|
23,888
|
18,548
|
1985-86
|
111,528
|
86,106
|
25,422
|
8,890
|
25,062
|
18,879
|
1986-87
|
116,673
|
90,005
|
26,668
|
9,695
|
26,423
|
19,569
|
1987-88
|
125,406
|
96,453
|
28,953
|
10,337
|
27,400
|
20,518
|
1988-89
|
132,840
|
99,688
|
33,152
|
10,700
|
28,780
|
22,145
|
1989-90
|
142,637
|
103,848
|
38,789
|
11,249
|
30,501
|
23,417
|
1990-91
|
151,353
|
108,765
|
42,588
|
11,518
|
34,532
|
22,928
|
1991-92
|
156,389
|
115,215
|
41,174
|
10,901
|
39,340
|
24,865
|
1992-93
|
161,401
|
122,576
|
38,825
|
10,939
|
40,365
|
26,544
|
1993-94
|
157,996
|
120,014
|
37,982
|
11,282
|
37,536
|
26,947
|
1994-95
|
160,785
|
118,739
|
42,046
|
10,693
|
35,326
|
26,313
|
1995-96
|
158,918
|
112,013
|
46,905
|
9,935
|
34,510
|
26,076
|
1996-97
|
149,793
|
104,820
|
44,973
|
8,661
|
33,986
|
22,162
|
1997-98
|
149,684
|
108,753
|
40,931
|
8,879
|
34,067
|
20,504
|
1998-99
|
152,787
|
111,393
|
41,394
|
8,781
|
34,665
|
25,523
|
1999-00
|
157,000
|
115,500
|
41,500
|
9,900
|
35,000
|
23,600
|
2000-01
|
158,000
|
116,000
|
42,000
|
9,400
|
36,000
|
22,600
|
2001-02
|
163,000
|
121,500
|
41,500
|
9,500
|
37,800
|
24,100
|
Source: Department
of Finance, Fiscal Reference Tables, September 1999; and Minister
of Finance, Budget Plan, February 2000.
From 1970 to 1988, total
net payments for Old Age Security increased by a factor of approximately
5.7 while those for the Guaranteed Income Supplement increased by a factor
of 12.5. The increase in total outlays is a function of two variables:
annual payments per recipient and the number of recipients. It is clear
that the major determinant of total OAS payments is the growth in recipient
population. If we had kept the real value of benefits constant at 1970
levels, the total OAS bill in 1988 would have been $9,373 million rather
than $10,774 million, a reduction of only 12.5%. This is not true of the
GIS, for which the major cause of expenditure increases has been the growth
in the real value of payments. If the real value of average GIS benefits
had been held constant at their 1970 levels, total payments would have
been $2,368 million in 1988, rather than $3,725 million, a reduction of
36%.
Why have real GIS payments
grown so much and what are their component parts? Does the growth of GIS
payments reflect an increasing incidence of poverty among the elderly
or does it rather represent an increasing generosity on the part of the
federal government? There are several ways of looking at these questions.
The growth in the number of GIS beneficiaries has been only slightly higher
than the growth in the number of OAS beneficiaries. Interestingly, though,
the number of recipients receiving the full benefit has steadily declined,
while the number receiving a partial benefit has grown to three times
its 1970 number.
The GIS was actually viewed
as a temporary measure when it was introduced. That was the period when
the Canada Pension Plan (CPP) came into existence. The GIS was intended
to help those who did not or could not participate in the CPP. As CPP
participation increased, however, the need for the GIS was to diminish.
Although the number of recipients of full benefits has declined as CPP
participation has increased, the number of recipients of partial benefits
has increased. One explanation for this is the nature of the tax back
regime. Income other than OAS payments is taxed back at a rate of 50%.
The point at which partial benefits cease to exist is when income is equal
to two times the level of GIS maximum benefits. This cut off point grows
with the GIS. The government has decided in the past that the GIS maximum
should grow in real terms and it has used ad hoc increases to achieve
this. (The GIS is also fully indexed to CPI changes.) This means that
the cut off point has also grown in real terms. As a result a greater
proportion of the elderly population has become eligible for partial GIS
payments.
To put the discussion
of OAS and GIS in perspective, we can look at their relative shares of
GDP. In 1970, OAS payments accounted for 1.8% of GDP. This ratio fell
to 1.6% and remained at that level until 1982 when it reverted to 1.8%,
where it has stayed. Because OAS benefits have increased only slightly
in real terms over this period, real GDP growth was able to offset the
increase in the OAS eligible population. The pattern for the GIS is quite
different. In 1970, GIS payments represented 0.3% of GDP. This ratio increased
to 0.5% in 1971 and remained at that level for ten years. In 1981 it increased
to 0.6% of GDP and in 1985 was at 0.7%. GIS maximum benefits have increased
substantially in real terms, and because of the nature of the tax back
mechanism, the eligible population has also increased. Thus a program
which was initially viewed as temporary has more than doubled in relation
to the size of the economy.
2.
The Seniors Benefit
As the government sought
to control its spending in order to reduce the deficit, the 1996 budget
announced the introduction of a new Seniors Benefit that was to
begin in 2001. It was to be a targeted and tax-free benefit aimed at elderly
families, and indexed fully to inflation. Eligibility and the size of
benefit were to be based upon family income. Once the new Seniors
Benefit came into existence, the OAS, GIS, Age Credit and Pension Income
Credit would have disappeared.
The proposed benefit attracted
considerable criticism, mostly on the grounds that certain provisions
would have reduced the incentive for those in some income categories to
save for retirement. The proposal was withdrawn. The government now argues
that, with its fiscal house in order, the need for dramatic reform is
lessened.
3.
(Un)Employment Insurance
Total Employment Insurance
(EI) benefits are today in the neighbourhood of $12,000 million annually.
These benefits totalled less than $550 million in fiscal year (FY)
1970 and reached a high of $19,065 million in 1992-93. A comparison of
these dollar amounts over more than two decades suffers from the same
problems that plague all such comparisons: changes in the relevant price
index and scale of the economy distort the magnitude of the differences.
Nevertheless, the growth in EI benefits is not an illusion. In the late
1960s they equalled 0.56% of GDP, whereas since 1982 they have exceeded
2% of GDP. Today they are closer to 1.4% of GDP. We cannot appeal to inflation
or increases in the absolute numbers of unemployed to explain this growth.
The obvious variable to
consider when explaining the ratio of EI benefits to GDP is the unemployment
rate. But this alone is not responsible. The unemployment rate since 1982
has been 2.7 times the average rate of that of the late 1960s, but the
ratio of EI benefits to GDP is 4 times higher. Something else has happened
to make the unemployment insurance system as expensive as it is.
Two institutional changes
help to explain the growth. In 1971 the system was significantly liberalized.
This increased benefit levels and made them taxable; it loosened eligibility
requirements; it increased both the duration of benefits and increased
overall coverage. It is estimated here, that this institutional change
increased the ratio of EI benefits to GDP by 0.56 percentage points for
every level of the unemployment rate. In addition to this direct effect,
the institutional change increased the cost of the EI program to the extent
that it increased the rate of unemployment. Estimates of this EI-induced
unemployment range from 0.4 to 1.9 percentage points.
In 1978, the unemployment
insurance system was tightened up in light of dissatisfaction with some
aspects of the 1971 reforms. It is apparent that these new changes were
successful: even though the average unemployment rate increased after
1978, the ratio of EI benefits to GDP actually fell. It is estimated here,
however, that the 1978 changes countered only about one-half of the 1971
changes. Thus the present system is still more generous than the one in
existence prior to 1971.
The recent cost of the EI
system is mostly the result of the high rates of unemployment that started
with the recession, though they have since fallen. The benefit/GDP ratio
varies approximately 0.5 percentage points for every 3 percentage point
change in the unemployment rate. The decline in unemployment slowed down
considerably in the early 1990s. The rapid decline in EI benefits is due
to reforms that tightened up the eligibility and benefit rules.
What is clear, nevertheless,
is the sensitivity of the size of the program to institutional change.
Such change has a major and rapid effect on the size of the EI program.
For example, implementing the recommendations of the Forget Commission
could have the same effect on program cost as a three percentage point
drop in the unemployment rate.
The federal government introduced
Bill C-21 in June 1989 in an attempt to reduce the disincentive effects
of unemployment insurance and to reduce federal expenditures in this field.
This bill imposed stricter entrance requirements for EI benefits, reduced
the duration of those benefits on average, and withdrew federal government
financial contributions to this program. It is expected these proposed
measures will save the government $1,900 million annually.
The Liberal government of
Prime Minister Chrétien initiated unemployment insurance reform early
in its mandate, looking to reduce program spending by close to $1,000
million per year. Legislation for the new Employment Insurance Program
received Royal Assent on 20 June 1996. It reduced maximum benefits, and
reduced benefits somewhat to repeat users as well as generally tightening
up the system. First announced in the Speech from the Throne, the extension
of parental leave from six months to one year was included in Budget 2000.
4. Family Allowances/Child
Tax Benefits
The historical pattern of
family allowance expenditures is relevant to this discussion for a number
of reasons. In the first place, family allowances were an important component
of federal spending on social development. By 1991, net family allowance
payments amounted to about $2,800 million and were delivered to over
3.7 million families. But this program is also interesting in that it
demonstrates how expenditure patterns can be totally misleading. Changes
in the design of the program since 1970 make it difficult to discuss trends.
The program started out as a modest non-taxable benefit available without
regard to income. It then became a taxable benefit in 1974 and was substantially
increased. In 1979, the level was reduced and a Child Tax Credit (CTC)
introduced.
The number of children for
whom family allowances are delivered, peaked in 1975 at 7.3 million.
In 1970, family allowance
payments amounted to 0.6% of GDP. This increased to 1.2% in 1974 as a
result of the big increase in gross benefits per child. The ratio of payments
to GDP declined to 0.9% over the next four years and then further declined
to 0.6%. This was mostly the result of the decrease in the number of eligible
children and the 1979 reduction when the CTC was introduced.
The Child Tax Credit was
technically considered to be a tax expenditure and as such did not show
up in expenditure or revenue figures. But such an exclusion is purely
arbitrary and the CTC could just as easily have been considered as an
expenditure with "tax back" provisions like the GIS. If we treat
it as such and combine it with the family allowance, the pattern of child
expenditures is as follows: from 0.6% of GDP in 1970, these expenditures
increased to 1.2% in the mid-1970s when the number of children peaked;
the ratio then declined slightly, only to jump up again to 1.3% with the
introduction of the CTC; finally, it fell to its 1990s level of 0.9% of
GDP as a consequence of a further decline in the client population.
The April 1989 federal budget
introduced a benefit reduction scheme which applied to Old Age Pensions
and Family Allowance Payments, taxing both through the personal income
tax system. Benefits were reduced by $0.15 for every dollar of individual
income in excess of $50,000. The Family Allowance Program no longer exists,
having been replaced by the Child Tax Benefit as of 1 January 1993.
Transfers to persons, which are now near record levels, would have been
even higher in the absence of this reform. The 1996 budget proposed to
double the working income supplement in two stages, to $1,000. This has
now been changed. The government is adding an additional $600 million
to the program and basing the supplement on the number of children in
a family. The 1999 budget announced increases in CTB amounts: $320 million
starting in July 1999, followed by another $750 million in 2000 and
$850 million in 2001. Budget 2000 announced further increases:
$475 million starting in July 2000, followed by $1,020 million
in 2001 and $1,350 million in 2002.
C. Debt Charges
The discussion above has
dealt with various program expenditures of the federal government. A large
and growing component of government spending, however, is interest charges
on accumulated government debt. In 1970 these charges amounted to $1,800
million whereas they could reach $40,000 million this fiscal year. As
a percentage of GDP, they have more than doubled, to almost 6%.
It is popular to blame this
component of expenditure on monetary policy rather than fiscal policy,
citing the role of high real interest rates since 1982-83. Debt charges
could be reduced substantially by a policy designed to reduce prevailing
interest rates, it is argued. For example, at the time of the release
of the 1988 Main Estimates, it was claimed that a one percentage point
drop in interest rates could reduce debt payments by $1.4 billion.
It is true that real interest
rates are today much higher than they were in the 1970s. But during that
period we experienced accelerating inflation which left ex post
real interest rates often at very low, even negative levels. The desirability
of repeating such an experience is not at all obvious. It is not at all
clear that the Bank of Canada could reduce real interest rates through
a policy of monetary expansion. Nor is it obvious that all of today's
high debt charges can be blamed solely on high interest rates. There is
another important variable to consider; namely, the stock of debt to which
these interest charges are applied.
In the first half of the
1970s, debt charges averaged 2.2% of GDP. This was associated with a falling
debt to GDP ratio and low, often negative, real interest rates. After
1976, debt charges rose steadily to over 4% of GDP even though real interest
rates continued to be relatively low. This was because the stock of debt
was growing. The debt to GDP ratio grew over this period as the federal
government started to run considerable deficits.
Starting in 1984, debt charges
exceeded 5% of GDP. During this time, while the stock of debt grew rapidly,
real interest rates were extremely high by recent standards. It is this
factor which has led some analysts to argue that high debt charges are
a matter for monetary policy.
To test this assertion we
estimated the effect on debt charges of a 3% real interest rate, starting
in fiscal year 1982. Although a 3% real rate is still high by the standards
of the 1970s, when real rates of interest were unusually low, it is compatible
with the long run interest rate experienced in Canada.
The average ratio of debt
charges to GDP since fiscal 1982 has been 4.8%. With a 3% real interest
rate this ratio would have fallen to 3.64% on average. The debt to GDP
ratio would have fallen marginally as well, from 59.47% to 57.4% at the
end of 1986-87. The average ratio of debt charges to GDP would, however,
still have been significantly higher than anything experienced in the
1970s. The impact of such a lowering of interest rates on the size of
the debt and corresponding debt charges has been overestimated. That action
limits the ratio of gross debt charges to gross public debt, as published
by the Department of Finance, to 3% in real terms. But a policy which
lowered interest rates today would affect only new borrowing. It would
be several years before a sustained drop in interest rates affected the
entire stock of outstanding debt.
D. Federal
Budgets of 1990, 1991 and 1992 and
the December
1992 Economic Statement
On 20 February 1990,
the Hon. Michael H. Wilson tabled his sixth budget. The highlight of this
budget was an expenditure control plan, designed to reduce total spending
by $6,111 million over two years and $16,689 million over the next five
years. This plan contained four elements. First, a number of programs,
most notably Canada Assistance Plan payments to Ontario, British Columbia
and Alberta, were to grow by no more than 5% per annum over the next two
years. Second, Established Programs Financing were frozen on a per capita
basis for two years. Third, some programs were reduced, including spending
on social housing, Health and Welfare and Secretary of State grants. Finally,
some programs were eliminated - these include the Canadian Exploration
Incentives Program, the OSLO oil sands project and the Polar 8 Icebreaker.
These measures were expected to reduce program spending to 14.2% of GDP
by 1994-95.
The main thrust of the 1991
budget was to extend by three years the expenditure control plan introduced
the year earlier. Forming part of this plan were a wage restraint program
for the Public Service of Canada and legislated limits on program spending.
The program spending restraint
legislation set out in the budget was a hybrid of the American Gramm-Rudman
deficit control limits and sunset legislation used at the American state
government level to control the growth of government programs. The budgetary
proposal limits total program spending from 1991-92 to 1995-96 to $615,300 million.
The limits for each year were to grow by an average of 3% per year. This
measure was intended to limit overall spending, so that any excess in
one year would not be added to the expenditure base but would have to
be offset in other years.
The 1992 budget extended
the Expenditure Control Plan even further as well as cutting $1,000 million
from 1992 spending. The poor performance of the Canadian economy had put
further pressure on the federal deficit, mainly through revenue reductions
but also because of some program spending increases. In response to these
developments, the government took further initiatives to curb and control
the cost of government operations by $ 3,600 million over a two-year
period. Some of these new measures included a 10% reduction in most grants
and subsidies in each of the next two years, a further two-year wage freeze
for public servants and politicians, and a 3% reduction in operating budgets.
In addition, the EI benefit rate for new beneficiaries was reduced from
60% of insurable wages to 57%. Those who quit their jobs without just
cause, or who were fired, lost eligibility for EI.
E.
The 1993 Federal Budget
This budget added a few
new elements of spending control to those announced in past budgets and
in the economic statement. The new measures, though, were small in comparison
with earlier moves.
Grants and contributions,
which had been cut by 10% for two years, were to be cut by 20% after 1996-97.
Reductions to regional development programs were also extended and some
federal-provincial development agreements were not renewed. Where previous
restraint measures had allowed for future increases, those increases were
now limited to 1.5% per year, the expected rate of inflation. This applied
to defence spending, international assistance, and the funding of university
research councils.
CMHC funding for social
housing was frozen at $2,000 million per year, while funding for the CBC
and VIA Rail was to be cut by $100 million per year after 1995-96. An
additional $300 million was to be taken from operating budgets in 1993-94
and 1994-95, with larger cuts thereafter. All in all, though, these additional
cuts would have their greatest impact several years in the future.
Despite all these cuts,
government operations increased from $17,150 million in 1991-92 to
$20,300 million in 1993-94, an 18.4% increase over two years.
Program spending was expected
to increase, according to this budget, by 1.7% per year from 1993-94 to
1997-98. This was just slightly above the rate of inflation. In the short
term, however, the growth in program spending was higher, masked by restructuring
of child benefits. Program spending in this year was expected to be 2.8%
higher than in 1992-93, with the following year's growth almost as high,
at 2.6%.
This budget met the requirements
of the Spending Control Act. In fact, cumulative spending to 1995-96
was expected to be $8,500 million less than allowable limits and the government
proposed that this underspending be incorporated in new, lower limits.
These spending limits were adjusted to account for the restructuring of
federal programs which moved some obligations out of the realm of program
spending.
F.
The 1994 Federal Budget
This budget projected stable
program spending to 1995-96. Any growth in total spending would be the
result of higher debt servicing costs.
This apparent stability
in program spending was due to the reforms put in place with respect to
the system of child benefits. Without these reforms, expenditures would
have grown; instead, tax revenue was expected to decline.
G.
The 1995 Federal Budget
From 1990 to 1993, federal
spending grew at a faster pace than revenues. By 1995, this was changing.
After 1994-95, program spending was expected to decline every year; by
1997 it would be $12,000 million less than in 1993-94, when it totalled
$120,000 million. As a proportion of GDP, program spending, including
restructuring charges, was expected to decline from 16.9% to 13.1%. While
program spending was declining, however, public debt charges were slated
to increase substantially. By 1996-97, they were expected to exceed $50,000
million (6.2% of GDP), compared to $38,000 million (5.3% of GDP) in 1993-94.
The government was able
to control spending on account of a major review and reduction in program
expenditures and government operating costs that were expected to result
in a 45,000-person decline in federal employment. Approximately 6,000
of the positions were expected to be transferred to the private sector,
while the remaining positions would disappear.
As part of these cuts, business
subsidies were to be reduced by 60% over three years and certain agricultural
subsidies were to be reduced or eliminated altogether. Program review
in departments that had been reviewed, (a 19% decrease) were expected
to result in spending levels in 1997-98 almost $10,000 million less than
in 1994-95.
In addition, the government
planned to combine the Canada Assistance Plan and Established Programs
Financing transfers into one block grant, starting in 1996-97. This "Canada
Social Transfer" would be based on a new formula resulting in a total
of $4,700 million in reduced transfers for 1996-97 and 1997-98. Provinces
were to have more say as to how they spent these funds, while federal
transfers would no longer be linked to provincial spending decisions.
The government's spending
projections also factored in a reform of unemployment insurance, which
was expected to save at least $700 million in 1996-97. Some small changes
were made to the Old Age Security system, with the promise of much more
to come following a review by the Minister of Human Resources Development.
The 1995 federal budget
announced $25,300 million in cumulative expenditure cuts over a three-year
period ending in 1997-98, with $17,000 million due to program review.
Only 16% of these cuts, however, were to take place in the first year.
H.
The 1996 Federal Budget
This budget, unlike the
1995 budget, did not introduce significant spending cuts. It did, however,
ensure that program spending would continue to fall, to $105,500 million
in 1998-99. This was in contrast to program spending of $118,700 million
in 1994-95.
The budget extended Program
Review, saving an additional $1,900 million in 1998-99. Some of the major
new announcements in the budget included a further 3.5% reduction in departmental
budgets in 1998-99, a phasing out of the dairy subsidy, an 18% reduction
in the postal subsidy, lower spending on VIA Rail and AECL, and more cuts
to defence. Some of these savings were re-allocated to other areas of
greater priority.
I.
The 1997 Federal Budget
This budget introduced a
number of new spending initiatives in priority areas. The overall impact
was small, and program spending continued on the downward track established
in earlier budgets.
New initiatives to promote
job growth included a $425-million top-up to the Canada Infrastructure
Works Program for 1997-98 (announced prior to the budget), and an $800-million
contribution in 1996-97 for the Canada Foundation for Innovation. The
Foundation was to finance a five-year infrastructure modernization initiative
for colleges and universities, research hospitals and not-for-profit research
institutes. Financing contributions by the Foundation would not have to
exceed 50% of any capital projects costs and were generally to be
kept at about 40% of the total. Although the governments contribution
was included in 1996-97 expenditures, funds were not to be disbursed for
capital projects until later. The Auditor General expressed some qualms
about the governments way of accounting for this expenditure, in
much the same way as he had questioned the previous years budget
accounting of the payment made to the three Atlantic provinces in relation
to the Harmonized Sales Tax.
Additional funding was also
provided for the Networks of Centres of Excellence, the Industrial Research
Assistance Program (IRAP), an extension of the Residential Rehabilitation
Assistance Program (RRAP), and additional funding for tourism promotion.
These additions to program spending were small and were not expected to
affect the downward trend in overall program spending, which by 1998-99,
at $103,500 million, was predicted would be just under 12% of GDP. The
budget also announced capital injections of $50 million each to the
Business Development Bank and the Farm Credit Corporation. While these
injections required financing from the federal government, they did not
constitute spending initiatives, since the government balance sheet would
show an associated asset.
The government also benefited
from low interest rates. It was expected that, by 1998-99, public debt
charges, at $46,500 million, would equal 5.3% of GDP, down from 6% of
GDP in 1995-96.
J.
The 1998 Federal Budget
This budget continued the
trend to reduce federal spending. It was planned that, as a proportion
of GDP, total federal spending in 1999-00 would be 30% less than it was
in 1992-93 and exactly one-third less than it was in 1984-85, when it
reached a peak of 24.6% of GDP. As can be seen from Figure 1, however,
the pace of decline was slowing down.
Program spending was expected
to equal 11.5% of GDP by 1999-00. This is in contrast to 17.8% of GDP
in 1992-93, and 19.6% in 1984-85. This measure of federal spending showed
even more dramatic declines, a 35% decline since 1992-93 and a 41% decline
since 1984-85. Indeed, the nominal dollar value of total and program spending
in 1999-00 was projected to be about the same as in 1990-91, nine years
earlier. This was also an unprecedented achievement.
Still, the 1998 budget introduced
a number of new spending initiatives that, when added to measures announced
before the budget, added up to $10,900 million in cumulative new spending
to the year 1999-00. Adding the increased Child Tax Benefit spending listed
by the budget as tax relief was expected to generate $12,000 million in
cumulative new spending over four years.
The largest single spending
initiative was the Canada Millennium Scholarship program. The government
was debiting $2,500 million for this program in 1997-98, even though it
had not actually forwarded the funds to the foundation until 1998. The
cumulative cost of the increase in the CHST cash floor ($12,500 million),
which was announced prior to the budget, was to be $4,100 million to the
year 1999-00. Other spending initiatives were directed to post-secondary
students, and complemented the new tax measures.
Also announced in the budget
were enhanced funding for the granting councils, additional funds for
Aboriginal programs, and money for AIDS initiatives.
K.
The 1999 Federal Budget
After the previous years
budgetary surplus, the government faced substantial demands for greater
social spending, primarily on the health care system. Several initiatives
were announced in that sector. Over the following five years, $11,500 million
were to be transferred to the provinces, exclusively for their health
care systems. Of this amount, $8,000 million would increase the CHST
cash floor and $3,500 million would be an immediate one-time supplement
to the CHST.
Even with this announcement,
federal spending in year 2000-01 was expected to be at its lowest level
in 50 years, accounting for 12.0% of GDP 0.6% percentage points
lower than was expected for 1999-2000.
Initiatives with respect
to knowledge and innovation were also announced in this budget. The Canada
Foundation for Innovation, whose main objective is the promotion of research
in the high-technology sector, was to receive additional funding. For
the first time in its history, the Canadian Space Agency was promised
substantial non-project related support from the federal government; $430 million
was to be invested over the next three years.
The Child Tax Benefit had
already been increased in the 1998 budget; however, the 1999 budget extended
these benefits to modest- and middle-income families by dedicating $300 million
to them. EI premiums were also to be reduced by a total amount of $465 million
in 1999-2000. In brief, the 1999 budget emphasized the health care system,
while providing all taxpayers with a small tax reduction.
L.
The 2000 Federal Budget
The budgetary surplus in
1998-99 was the second in a row. After announcing in Economic and Fiscal
Update 1999 that there would be large surpluses over the next five years,
the government introduced a tax-cutting plan in Budget 2000. Nevertheless,
the federal government also introduced new spending initiatives: $900 million
of additional funding to the Canada Foundation for Innovation, $900 million
over five years to create 2,000 new university research chairs across
Canada, $160 million to Genome Canada to advance the study of genes
and biotechnology, $700 million over four years to improve environmental
technologies and practices, and additional funding for infrastructure
projects to be negotiated with provincial and municipal governments.
The CHST was increased by
an additional $2,500 million in a one-time payment in fiscal year 1999-2000.
After many years of budget
cuts, funding for defence started to rise again in 1998-99. Substantial
additional funding was announced in Budget 2000: an increase of $634 million
in 1999-2000, $546 million in 2000-2001 and more than $500 million
in every subsequent year. Other departments and agencies were given increases
in their funding for operating and capital purposes, for a total of $505
million in 1999-2000 and $1.2 billion the following year. Nevertheless,
project spending as a percentage of GDP is still projected to decline
to 11.6%.
The most important element
in Budget 2000 is the restoration of full indexation for tax brackets
and tax credits, an initiative also extended to the Child Tax Benefit.
PARLIAMENTARY ACTION
In a very real sense, the
history of government expenditures is the result of parliamentary action
in one form or another. Approximately once a year, the Minister of Finance
presents a budget to Parliament in which the government's future spending
and taxation plans are outlined. In addition, almost every bill passed
in Parliament has some impact on government expenditures.
CHRONOLOGY
June
1971 - The EI system was substantially expanded and liberalized with the
passage of Bill C-229.
January
1974 - Family allowance payment was increased to $20 per month per child
and began to be treated as taxable income. The monthly payment also became
subject to indexation.
1977
- Bill C-27 was introduced and passed in 1977 to tighten up the liberalized
EI system. It increased eligibility requirements and reduced maximum weeks
of benefits for a wide range of EI recipients.
1978
- Child Tax Credit was introduced. Maximum benefit was set at $200 per
eligible child.
1979
- Family allowance benefits were reduced by about 22% starting in January.
1983
and 1984 - Indexation factors for government expenditures were limited
to 6% and 5% respectively.
May
1985 - The federal budget proposed limiting indexation to CPI changes
in excess of 3 percentage points.
November
1986 - The Commission of Inquiry on Unemployment Insurance (C.E. Forget,
Chairman) released its Report calling for major changes to the EI system
in order to return the program to its insurance function.
October
1994 - The Minister of Finance, the Honourable Paul Martin, published
the Economic and Fiscal Update.
December
1994 - The House of Commons Standing Committee on Finance tabled its report
"Confronting Canada's Deficit Crisis."
November
1999 - The Minister of Finance, the Honourable Paul Martin, in his presentation
of the Economic and Fiscal Update, forecast continuing budgetary surpluses
along with moderate growth in expenditures.
SELECTED REFERENCES
Bird,
R.M. The Growth of Government Spending in Canada. Canadian Tax
Papers No. 51. Canadian Tax Foundation, Toronto, July 1970.
Canada,
Department of Finance. The Fiscal (Budget) Plan. Ottawa, various
dates.
Dingledine,
G. A Chronology of Response, The Evolution of Unemployment Insurance
from 1940 to 1980. Employment and Immigration Canada, Ottawa, 1981.
Gauthier,
Gilles. Federal Public Expenditures Part I: Growth. BP 119-E,
Research Branch, Library of Parliament, Ottawa.
Horry,
I.D. and M.A. Walker. Government Spending Facts. The Fraser Institute,
Vancouver, 1990.
Prince,
M.J. How Ottawa Spends, 1986-87: Tracking the Tories. Methuen,
Toronto, 1986.
Saunders,
P. and F. Klau. "The Role of the Public Sector." OECD Economic
Studies, No. 4, Spring 1985.
The National
Finances. Canadian Tax Foundation,
Toronto, various issues.
* The original version of this Current
Issue Review was published in January 1987; the paper has been regularly
updated since that time.
|
|